Skip to main content
Erschienen in: BMC Medicine 1/2021

Open Access 01.12.2021 | Research article

Cost-effectiveness modelling to optimise active screening strategy for gambiense human African trypanosomiasis in endemic areas of the Democratic Republic of Congo

verfasst von: Christopher N. Davis, Kat S. Rock, Marina Antillón, Erick Mwamba Miaka, Matt J. Keeling

Erschienen in: BMC Medicine | Ausgabe 1/2021

Abstract

Background

Gambiense human African trypanosomiasis (gHAT) has been brought under control recently with village-based active screening playing a major role in case reduction. In the approach to elimination, we investigate how to optimise active screening in villages in the Democratic Republic of Congo, such that the expenses of screening programmes can be efficiently allocated whilst continuing to avert morbidity and mortality.

Methods

We implement a cost-effectiveness analysis using a stochastic gHAT infection model for a range of active screening strategies and, in conjunction with a cost model, we calculate the net monetary benefit (NMB) of each strategy. We focus on the high-endemicity health zone of Kwamouth in the Democratic Republic of Congo.

Results

High-coverage active screening strategies, occurring approximately annually, attain the highest NMB. For realistic screening at 55% coverage, annual screening is cost-effective at very low willingness-to-pay thresholds (<DOLLAR/>20.4 per disability adjusted life year (DALY) averted), only marginally higher than biennial screening (<DOLLAR/>14.6 per DALY averted). We find that, for strategies stopping after 1, 2 or 3 years of zero case reporting, the expected cost-benefits are very similar.

Conclusions

We highlight the current recommended strategy—annual screening with three years of zero case reporting before stopping active screening—is likely cost-effective, in addition to providing valuable information on whether transmission has been interrupted.
Begleitmaterial
Additional file 1 Figures S1–S10 and Tables S1–S7. Supporting information for the manuscript including further details of the gHAT modelling, explanations and derivations of all net monetary benefit parameters, a short analysis of a different health zone, details on reactive screening, some additional results, and a table of how we satisfied the five principles of the Neglected Tropical Diseases Modelling Consortium. Figure S1 – Schematic of the compartmental model for gHAT infection dynamics in humans (low- and high-risk) and tsetse. Figure S2 – Histograms of screening coverage for (A) Kwamouth and (B) Mosango. Figure S3 – The cost-effectiveness of active screening strategies for the health zone of Mosango. Figure S4 – The effect of the number of zero-detections in reactive screening on the cost effective acceptability curves (CEACs). Figure S5 – Active and reactive screenings information. Figure S6 – The time interval between observing a passive detection and resuming reactive screening for different values of active zero-detections. Figure S7 – Distributions of (A) the change in cost of an active screening strategy and (B) the number of DALYs averted for 30- and 100-year time-horizons. Figure S8 – Theoretical optimum strategy for mean simulation of infection dynamics given WTP and pt. Figure S9 – Mean change in costs relative to the assumed interventions for a village with 55% screening coverage annually with 3 zero-detections. Figure S10 – Linear fits through the results of different active screening strategies from Fig. 5. Table S1 – The transition rates of the Markov-chain gHAT-infection model and additional ordinary differential equation component of the model. Table S2 – Parameter notation and values for the gHAT infection model. Table S3 – Net monetary benefit parameters that determine our manuscript parameters. Table S4 – Proportion of people receiving each type of treatment. Table S5 – Formulation of manuscript parameters from cost data. Table S6 – The values that determine the linear fits for each strategy in Figure S10. Table S7 – PRIME-NTD criteria fulfillment.
Hinweise

Supplementary Information

The online version contains supplementary material available at (https://​doi.​org/​10.​1186/​s12916-021-01943-4).

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Abkürzungen
gHAT
Gambiense human African trypanosomiasis
NMB
Net monetary benefit
HAT
Human African trypanosomiasis
DALY
Disability-adjusted life year
WHO
World Health Organization
EOT
Elimination of transmission
CATT
Card agglutination test for trypanosomiasis
RDT
Rapid diagnostic test
DRC
Democratic Republic of Congo
DIC
Deviance information criterion
YLL
Years of life lost
YLD
Years lived with disability
WTP
Willingness-to-pay
GDP
Gross demoestic product
ACER
Average cost-effectiveness ratio
ICER
Incremental cost-effectiveness ratio
CEAC
Cost-effectiveness acceptability curve
CEAF
Cost-effectiveness acceptability frontier

Background

Despite the continued decline in the annual number of reported cases of gambiense human African trypanosomiasis (gHAT), accounting for fewer than 1000 new cases reported in 2019 [1, 2], the disease persists in many of the historically endemic sites in Western and Central Africa. This vector-borne disease, transmitted by a bite from a tsetse infected with the parasite Trypanosoma brucei gambiense, is typically—although not always—fatal when untreated [3]. Human African trypanosomiasis (HAT), which includes both gambiense and rhodesiense forms, caused an estimated 1360 deaths in 2019 and approximately 82,615 disability-adjusted life years (DALYs), of which the majority were caused by gHAT [4]. Gambiense HAT has been targeted for elimination by the World Health Organization (WHO); first, for elimination as a public health problem by 2020 and then for elimination of transmission (EOT) by 2030 [2, 5]. To achieve these targets, there are several recommended strategies to reduce the transmission and burden of the infection, which are constituted primarily of the medical interventions of active screening and passive surveillance.
Passive surveillance depends on the ability of fixed health centres to test for the infection and carry out treatment on self-presenting individuals, typically upon the onset of symptoms [6]. Screening and treating infected individuals both allows the infected people to be saved from a potentially fatal disease, but it also prevents further spread of infection via tsetse.
Traditionally, the most effective form of controlling gHAT infection, however, has been active screening and treatment [79]. Active screening is carried out by mobile teams that travel to villages in focal disease regions and target the screening of the whole population for gHAT; those determined to have the infection can then be treated at the closest health facility offering treatment. The initial screening test is typically a serological test for the presence of the antibody called the card agglutination test for trypanosomiasis (CATT) [10], although recently rapid diagnostic tests (RDTs) have also been utilised for screening [1113]. Confirmation of the infection is then carried out via microscopic examination; traditionally, this is followed by staging of the disease, which consists of a lumbar puncture to determine whether the parasite has infected the central nervous system—considered the second stage of disease [14]. However, the recently approved drug, fexinidazole [15], can be used to treat both disease stages (except for patients with neuro-psychiatric symptoms and signs suspicious of advanced second stage disease) and so may remove the need for lumbar puncture in most cases, although retaining the requirement of parasitological confirmation [16].
Active screening has been very effective in reducing case numbers and still plays an important role in maintaining surveillance and treatments where access is problematic, yet it is an expensive intervention in terms of both time and money [11, 17]. As local elimination of gHAT occurs in focal areas, active screening will likely be scaled back and gHAT testing will become better integrated into fixed health facilities, as resources can be reallocated and it becomes unnecessary to screen entire village populations for the infection [18]. In this situation, reactive screening can be implemented, whereby after a number of successive active screenings in which no cases are detected, the screening stops unless a new case is passively reported, upon which a ‘reactive’ screen would occur [12]. Several active screening strategies have been proposed, including a recommendation of three repeated screening rounds with 1-year [19] or 6-month intervals [20]. WHO guidelines currently recommend annual screening for three years of zero case reporting before stopping in previously endemic villages [5].
Mathematical models of gHAT have been used for the prediction of future case numbers and evaluation of a range of plausible control strategies [2129]. However, these have typically considered the infection dynamics and the impact of interventions without accounting for the costs of implementing such strategies. Here, we explicitly use a stochastic model of gHAT infection in a village population, developed in Davis et al. [26], to simulate different plausible active screening programmes alongside passive surveillance, allowing us to quantify the relative costs of implementation as well as the health effects compared to a baseline of passive surveillance (the comparator strategy). We use parameters matched to screening and incidence data from the health zone Kwamouth, in Mai-Ndombe province of the Democratic Republic of Congo (DRC) (formerly in Bandundu province). Kwamouth is in a historically high-endemicity gHAT area of the DRC, the country that contributes 70% of all global gHAT cases in 2019 [2]. We also present results from a moderate-endemicity health zone, Mosango (see Additional file 1: Figure S3) [5, 11, 22, 24, 26, 3059].
The costs of gHAT interventions have been previously been evaluated [11, 46, 47, 51] and the different strategies have been considered for large populations [54, 60]. We consider the effect of active screening on individual villages in the drive for EOT, by determining how active screening can be best implemented to achieve this goal whilst providing value for money.

Methods

Mathematical modelling

To capture the effects of different active screening strategies and the underlying infection dynamics on a village population, we use a stochastic compartmental model [26]. The stochasticity incorporates the chance events involved in infection transmission into the mechanistic model and is better suited than a deterministic model for the purpose of optimising active screening for a village population. This is because the population, and hence the number of people infected, is small and so, for the pre-elimination setting, local elimination of gHAT can be substantially affected by chance events, and the probability of those chance events. A deterministic formulation, which captures average dynamics, would be less suitable to capture the chance events associated with village level elimination of infection.
In the model, individuals in the human population are classified as either high-risk or low-risk [22], whereby the high-risk population—a small minority, which has been previously estimated to be 9.8% in the study health zone of Kwamouth [30]—have a higher exposure to tsetse and do not participate in active screening. The model structure is supported by anecdotal evidence that there is a fraction of the population, typically working males that work by the rivers, which is the habitat of tsetse [61], and who are absent for active screening in the villages [32]. Furthermore, previous modelling work indicates that humans have heterogeneous exposure to tsetse [22, 25, 62]. Rock et al. [22] fitted several risk structures for humans and, using the deviance information criterion (DIC), the model with the risk structure given here best matched to data on screening and incidence from the WHO HAT Atlas [40, 41].
The model classifies a person’s infection status as susceptible SH, exposed (or latent) EH, stage 1 infection I1H, stage 2 infection I2H and hospitalised (and temporarily removed) RH. On exposure to the parasite and upon the bite of an infected tsetse, a person will progress through these infection stages, unless detected in active screening and so treated and moved directly to the hospitalised class. Stage 2 infection is defined as the time when trypanosomes have crossed the blood–brain barrier [63]. There is an additional rate defined as the time when people change infection status from stage 1 infection to hospitalisation to simulate people being treated through passive surveillance.
In addition, tsetse are explicitly modelled as the proportion of flies that are in the states of teneral (unfed and more susceptible to infection than fed flies [64]) SV, non-teneral yet uninfected GV, exposed (or latent) EV and infected IV. The dynamics of the tsetse are modelled with proportions using ordinary differential equations, since the exact number of tsetse that interact with a given population is difficult to determine (although relative tsetse abundance is being mapped in some areas [65]). However, the effective density ratio, the product of the number of tsetse in a population per human and the probability of human infection per single infective bite, can be inferred by model fitting to the WHO HAT Atlas data [40, 41]. A full description of the mathematical equations in the infection model and the parameters used (taken from Crump et al. [30], as the median of the distributions inferred using Markov chain Monte Carlo (MCMC) methodology and the aggregate annual data from the WHO HAT Atlas in Kwamouth) can be found in Additional file 1: Table S1 and Table S2.

Simulating active screening

In villages targeted for active screening, we consider how the infection dynamics are affected by: the screening coverage c; the screening interval t; active zero-detections za; reactive zero-detections zr (see Table 1). This is modelled by taking all combinations of c,t,za and zr for the values c= 0, 1, 5, 10, 15, 20, 25, 30, 35, 40, 45, 50, 55, 60, 65, 70, 75, 80, 85, 90, t= 0.25, 0.33, 0.5, 0.67, 0.75, 1, 1.25, 1.5, 1.75, 2, 2.5, 3, 3.5, 4, 4.5, 5 years, za= 1, 2, 3, 4, 5 screenings, and zr= 1, 2, 3 screenings. The risk structure of the model means that the screening coverage is assumed to have a maximum of 90%, since only the low-risk human population participate (randomly) in active screening.
Table 1
Descriptions of the variables used for defining an active screening strategy
Variable
Name
Definition
Value range
c
Screening coverage
Proportion of the village population screened in a visit.
0–90%
t
Screening interval
Time between active screening visits to a village.
0.25–5 years
za
Active zero-detections
Number of consecutive active screenings where no cases are detected for the cessation of active screening.
1–5 screenings
zr
Reactive zero-detections
Number of consecutive reactive screenings where no cases are detected for the cessation of reactive screening.
1–3 screenings
The specified screening procedure is then implemented in the model by using the screening coverage to randomly select a proportion c of the population from the low-risk sub-population, which move into the hospitalised class if they are correctly identified as being exposed to the infection after each screening interval. This process is stopped after number of zero-detections equal to za. However, if the infection has not been eliminated after the active screening has been halted, there is still a chance that a new case can be reported by the individual attending a fixed facility to be tested for the infection. The model explicitly incorporates under-reporting of passive case detections, such that only 27% of cases undetected by active screening will be detected by passive surveillance. The value of this parameter was estimated in fitting to this model structure, and is taken as the median of the distribution inferred using MCMC methodology applied to the aggregate annual data from Kwamouth from the WHO HAT Atlas [40, 41].
Reactive screening is the result of the detection of a case in passive surveillance after active screening has been stopped (see Additional file 1: Figure S5). Thus, we restart the screening procedure as reactive screening upon identification of passive cases, stopping again after the given number of consecutive reactive zero-detections, zr.
The WHO aims for high screening coverage in active screenings for villages in gHAT-endemic foci, but just how high that coverage ought to be is not prescribed. Moreover, guidelines and previous modelling work suggest these screenings should continue annually until there have been three consecutive years of no new cases, followed by a further screening after three years if there are no detected cases [5, 26, 66]. Our modelling aims to provide evidence in support of this strategy or recommend how the strategy could be adapted to make more efficient use of resources.

Economic modelling

Cost-effectiveness metric

The cost of an active screening strategy is a function of several component costs: implementing the screening test, confirmation of the infection, carrying out treatments, setting up and maintaining the mobile screening teams. Moreover, active screening may impact the number of passive tests and treatments performed. In the current work, we do not consider the additional costs of passive surveillance, such as capital costs, only the costs directly affected by active screening. The costs of active screening strategies will vary depending on the type of screening test and treatment used, and also the type of mobile screening team; whilst a traditional truck team that can carry more tests and equipment, such as a generator, a motorbike team that can reach more remote villages [46, 67].
As well as considering the changes in monetary costs, we want to consider the change in the health benefit of implementing different active screening programmes; therefore, we consider the number of DALYs averted [68]. The number of DALYs are the discounted sum of the number of years of life lost (YLL) and years lived with disability (YLD), where YLL is the number of years of life lost due to premature death and YLD is the number of years of healthy years lost with a weighting for the severity of the condition [69]. Therefore, the benefit of an active screening programme is measured by averting DALYs, and we do not attempt to quantify any additional benefits of achieving elimination. We calculate the number of DALYs averted by a particular screening strategy against a comparator consisting of passive surveillance and no active screening.
We evaluate the net monetary benefit (NMB) to assess the cost-effectiveness using a 30-year time-horizon. For each active screening strategy, the net monetary benefit (NMB) was calculated as:
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {}\text{NMB} = \:& \text{WTP}\times\text{DALYs averted} \\ \:& - \text{Cost of active screening strategy compared}\\&\quad \text{to passive surveillance only}. \end{array} $$
(1)
The net monetary benefit is conventionally conditioned on the willingness-to-pay (WTP), or the maximum amount of money that the funder is prepared (willing) to pay to avert one additional DALY over and above the comparator, namely implementing only passive surveillance but no active screening. The change in costs is the cost of implementing the active screening strategy, including the consequential change in cost of passive surveillance, minus the cost of baseline passive surveillance. A particular strategy is more efficient than the comparator strategy at that particular WTP if the NMB is positive. In the context of uncertainty, operationalised by repeated draws of the simulation, the optimal strategy will have the highest mean NMB. Because the NMB is conditioned on the WTP, we consider a range of fixed WTP thresholds, such that decision-makers can heed recommendations according to the typical cost-effective thresholds in their programmes.
In addition to the WTP, the NMB will be affected by the population size of a village, NH, the proportion of infections that go undetected by active screening but that are detected and treated passively pt, and the initial level of infection in the population.

Contextualising willingness-to-pay or cost-effectiveness thresholds

The correct WTP is the cause of much debate. Typically, the WTP is taken as the product of the gross domestic product (GDP) per capita of a country and a multiplying factor. This factor, WTPc, is traditionally set to 3 [70] for ‘cost-effective’ strategies and to 1 for ‘very cost-effective’ strategies. More recently, it has been remarked that this is too high for low-income countries [71].
The practical WTP in DRC in the past has been estimated to be between <DOLLAR/>5–<DOLLAR/>230 [72] per DALY, or between <DOLLAR/>70-<DOLLAR/>320 for Sub-Saharan African low-income countries [73]. The WHO would previously consider a strategy ‘very cost-effective’ if the WTP equals the GDP/capita (i.e. <DOLLAR/>557 in 2018 for DRC) or as ‘cost-effective’ when a strategy was optimal at a WTP ≥3 times the GDP per capita (i.e. <DOLLAR/>1671 in 2018 in DRC).
We also note that in the context of elimination, a funder may be willing to pay more for the additional benefit of reducing the number of infections to zero, but we simply leave this choice to the funder.
In accordance with WHO recommendations, we show the optimal strategies for a range of WTP thresholds without comment, as we provide guidance, rather than prescriptions, on what the thresholds should be as that is beyond our scope as modellers [74, 75].

Economic model inputs

To evaluate the NMB, we consider all component costs and the associated health benefits of implementing an active screening strategy compared to passive surveillance alone. However, we do not consider out-of-pocket expenses, therefore framing the model from the perspective of the funder of the programme. Since we are considering the NMB of an active screening strategy, we only consider costs impacted by active screening but we do not consider costs that are fixed across all strategies, such as maintaining a fixed health centre. We note that the total treatment costs will depend on the quantity of active screening carried out and additionally on the proportion of infections that are detected passively. Fitting to the WHO data indicates that around 27% of the infections that progress to Stage 2 and are not found in active screening are detected through passive surveillance, with the remainder of infections going unreported [30]. We can make the worst-case assumption that all these reported infections are treated, but none of the unreported infections are treated and will therefore die outside the healthcare system (pt=27%). Alternatively, we can use a higher value of the parameter pt to assume more people are treated that are reported in passive surveillance. The parameter pt takes values in the interval 27–100%, such that the proportion of infections being treated is between only those reported being treated and all infection being treated.
Using the formulation of the NMB given by Eq. 1, we then define the constituent parts of the equation as follows:
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} \text{WTP} = &\:{WTP}_{c} G, \end{array} $$
(2)
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} \text{DALYs} & \:\text{averted} \\ =& \: D_{1} \left(1-p_{t}\right) \sum_{t}\left(\text{Change exits from stage 2}\right.\\&\qquad\qquad\left. \text{infection}\right)(t)\zeta(t) \end{array} $$
(3)
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {}& + D_{2} \int \left(\text{Change in stage 1 infections}\right)(t)\zeta(t)\,\text{d}t \end{array} $$
(4)
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {}& + D_{3} \int \left(\text{Change in stage 2 infections}\right)(t)\zeta(t)\,\text{d} t, \end{array} $$
(5)
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {}\text{Change} & \:\text{in costs} \\ {}=& \: C_{1}N_{H} \left(\text{Years of active screening}\right)\zeta(t) \end{array} $$
(6)
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {}& + C_{2}N_{H}\left(\text{Active screening visits}\right)\zeta(t) \end{array} $$
(7)
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {}& + C_{3} \sum_{t}\left(\text{Number of people in active screening}\right)\\ &\quad(t)\zeta(t) \end{array} $$
(8)
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {}&+ \left(C_{4}+C_{5}\right) \sum_{t}\left(\text{Active screening true positives}\right.\\ &\quad \left.\text{in Stage 1}\right)(t)\zeta(t) \end{array} $$
(9)
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {}&+ \left(C_{4}+C_{6}\right) \sum_{t}\left(\text{Active screening true positives}\right.\\ &\quad \left.\text{in Stage 2}\right)(t)\zeta(t) \end{array} $$
(10)
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {}&+ C_{4} \sum_{t}\left(\text{Active screening false positives}\right)(t)\zeta(t) \end{array} $$
(11)
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {}&+ C_{7} \sum_{t}\left(\text{Change in stage 1 passive infections}\right)\\ &\quad(t)\zeta(t) \end{array} $$
(12)
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {}& + C_{8} p_{t}\sum_{t}\left(\text{Change in stage 2 passive infections}\right)\\ &\quad(t)\zeta(t) \end{array} $$
(13)
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {}&+ C_{9} \sum_{t}\left(\text{Treatment of stage 1 cases}\right)(t)\zeta(t) \end{array} $$
(14)
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {}&+ C_{10} \sum_{t}\left(\text{Treatment of stage 2 cases}\right)(t)\zeta(t). \end{array} $$
(15)
The willingness-to-pay, in 2018 US dollars per DALY, is split into the GDP per capita of the DRC, G, and a multiplying factor, WTPc as is common in the literature [70] (Eq. 2). For the health benefit of the intervention, the DALYs averted are the discounted sum of the number of years of life lost (YLL) and years lived with disability (YLD). The number of years of life lost is given by the sum of the change in number of people that exit the Stage 2 infection class multiplied by both the proportion of these infections not treated (1−pt) and the discounted average years of life lost per death (Eq. 3). The number of years lived with disability is given by the total time spent in each infection class multiplied by the associated disability weight (Eqs. 4 and 5).
The change in costs is simply the costs incurred by implementing the active screening strategy and the effect on costs of operating passive surveillance, given as a capital cost of active screening (Eq. 6) and the recurrent cost of operating each visit (Eq. 7), the number of screening tests carried out (Eq. 8), confirmation of the infection and stage determination for the true positive (Eqs. 9 and 10) and negative confirmation for the false positives (Eq. 11), the change in testing, confirmation and stage determination for passive infections (Eqs. 12 and 13), and the treatment of detected cases (Eqs. 14 and 15).
To calculate both the health benefit costs and implementation costs we use an annual discount rate of 3%, denoted in the equation by ζ(t)= exp(−δt). This is in line with standard conventions and arises through the assumption that value for society will decrease over time [42]. The time-horizon used is 30 years, which is sufficient to capture almost all the costs of the active screening programme (see Additional file 1: Figure S7). The cost parameters are fixed values composed as a sum of the cost of the test or treatment, the cost of implementation and the cost of hospitalisation [54]. These costs are also dependent on the type of treatment; we primarily consider active screening to use the CATT algorithm, whilst treatment is principally with fexinidazole with some Stage 1 and Stage 2 infections using pentamidine and NECT respectively where necessary (see Additional file 1: Table S4). We also consider the additional treatment strategies of only pentamidine and NECT, and only fexinidazole (see Additional file 1: Figure S9) and note that results for acoziborole could be computed using the accompanying app, which presents results for user inputted cost parameter values (see https://​christopherdavis​.​shinyapps.​io/​optimising-ghat-active-screening/​). We expect fexinidazole to be the standard treatment in 2020 for most gHAT patients [16], and acoziborole could replace it as a single dose cure a few years later if it passes phase III clinical trials and receives an appropriate recommendation [76] (see Additional file 1: Figure S9). Cost and health parameters are shown in Table 2 with full explanations in Additional file 1.
Table 2
Parameters for calculating the NMB
Parameter
Name
Value
WTPc
Willingness-to-pay per DALY
Varies
G
GDP per capita for the DRC1
<DOLLAR/>457.85
D1
Discounted average years of life lost per death
21.03 years
D2
Stage 1 disability weight
0.1330
D3
Stage 2 disability weight
0.5432
C1
Active screening capital cost per person
<DOLLAR/>0.22
C2
Active screening recurrent cost per person
<DOLLAR/>0.77
C3
Active screening test per person2
<DOLLAR/>1.03
C4
Confirmation per person3
<DOLLAR/>10.96
C5
Stage determination per person in stage 13
<DOLLAR/>1.59
C6
Stage determination per person in stage 23
<DOLLAR/>17.21
C7
Passive screening person in stage 13,4
<DOLLAR/>14.17
C8
Passive screening person in stage 23,4
<DOLLAR/>29.79
C9
Stage 1 treatment per person5
<DOLLAR/>85.23
C10
Stage 2 treatment per person6
<DOLLAR/>561.78
NH
Population size
Varies
12018 value used. 2We assume the use of the card agglutination test for trypanosomiasis (CATT) test. 3We assume confirmation is by microscopy using a blood sample, lymph node aspiration (LNA) and mini Anion Exchange Centrifugation Technique (mAECT). 4Passive screening includes the screening test (CATT), outpatient consultation, confirmation and stage determination if appropriate. 5We assume the use of both pentimidine and fexinidazle in proportions described in Additional file 1: Table S4. 6We assume the use of both nifurtimox-eflornithine combination therapy (NECT) and fexinidazole in proportions described in Additional file 1: Table S4
Values are given as the mean value. For more detailed calculations of these cost parameters see Additional file 1

Results

Breakdown of costs of active screening

We use the stochastic compartmental model, refined from Davis et al. [26], to simulate different strategies for active screening. We first consider an active screening strategy with a typical screening coverage of 55% (see Additional file 1: Figure S2), carried out annually, and with three active zero-detections and one reactive zero-detection required for the cessation of screening (c=55%, t=1 year, za=3, and zr=1). We assume a village population of size NH=1000 starting from endemic equilibrium (as determined from the deterministic version of the model), and with 27% of infections undetected in active screening treated passively (pt=27%). We calculate mean values of one million stochastic realisations of the process. For this strategy, the prevalence in both the human and tsetse populations rapidly decays towards zero (Fig. 1a). The annual cost of implementing this strategy also decreases with time (Fig. 1b); this is in part due to 3% discounting, the method of adjusting future costs to present-day values (which is applied to both costs and DALYs averted) [42], but also because decreasing the prevalence of infections in the population reduces the required number of treatments. Even with no active screening, infections may die out in the village due to ‘stochastic fade out’, when local disease extinction occurs purely by chance. There is a only a small annual decrease in costs around twelve years, since the difference in the number of infections treated in passive surveillance is smaller in later years. However, costs decay towards zero as the probability of local gHAT elimination increases with time; whilst some recurrent costs will remain, the number of treatments will decline in time with the corresponding reduction in infections. In addition, the costs also decrease when the consecutive zero-detection threshold is reached, as the cost of the active screening is completely removed. With the assumption that pt=27% and c=55%, the number of DALYs averted will initially increase each year because more people are treated after detection during active screening. However, in later years, DALYs averted will decline due to fewer infections under either strategy, implying that the differential impact in the active screening strategy (versus passive surveillance alone) is most substantial in the early years of implementation because both the strategies and passive surveillance are expected to lead to elimination, albeit at a different speed (Fig. 1b).
A breakdown of the components of the NMB of implementing this active screening strategy shows that the biggest costs are the treatment from active screening, the recurrent costs of the active screening and screening populations with the CATT test (Fig. 1c). However, assuming a WTP of 50% of the GDP per capita of the DRC (WTPc=0.5 giving WTP equal to <DOLLAR/>280.89 [77]) the monetary benefit in reducing the years of life lost is dominant and the biggest factor in maximising the NMB. The total NMB (black bars) shows the full benefit of this active screening strategy is always positive with WTPc=0.5 and so, on average, this strategy is better than the comparator of no active screening. Further into the future, the NMB moves closer to zero, both because of discounting and because there is a higher probability the infection will be locally eliminated, and so active screening not required. Note that the NMB of passive surveillance is positive because the introduction of active screening and treatment means that fewer passive confirmations and treatments will need be carried out, reducing the cost. The table in Fig. 1c shows the NMB breakdown in full.

Drivers of net monetary benefit across strategies

We performed a four-way sensitivity analysis of the NMB for the WTP, the treatment coverage in passive surveillance pt, the screening coverage c and screening interval t (Fig. 2). We considered the mean value of the NMB for one million simulations for every screening strategy considering screening coverage c and screening interval t for a large number of values (stated in Methods and Materials), but discretising WTP and pt to three and two values respectively for the presentation here. To view how the exact optima change with these model parameters and all the specified values for the cost and benefit parameters (including, treating WTP and pt as continuous variables) visit the supplementary R Shiny [57] app. This app allows the sensitivity of the optimal solution to be found on any updated costings for the active screening strategies.

The interaction between WTP and pt.

The NMB for some strategies is highly dependent on both the WTP and the proportion of passive infections treated (pt), with (1−pt) suffering disease-induced mortality, but the impacts of these factors on NMB are neither linear nor consistent. For instance, at low values of pt (pt=27%), the adoption of active screening strategies (of any frequency or coverage) is substantially different in the WTP value range of 0–0.5, but increasingly high WTP values would not yield different strategies. However, at high values of pt (pt=100%), the adoption of active screening strategies at any frequency or coverage level are incumbent on very high WTP values.

The impact of WTP and pt on optimal values of screening coverage and interval.

When assumptions about WTP and pt are fixed, the screening coverage has a greater impact on whether the NMB is positive than the screening interval. Low screening coverage levels (< 20%) can be insufficient to obtain a positive NMB, whilst the screening interval does not change the sign of the NMB for most coverage levels, unless the interval is very small (< 0.5 years). The question of what value to fix for WTP and pt has important implications on the optimal choice of screening coverage and optimal screening interval.
First, the optimal screening interval will be approximately one year under all assumptions of passive surveillance treatment coverage (pt) and WTP (yellow dots in all panels of Fig. 2). For WTPc=0.5 and pt=27% (our standard assumption), the maximum mean NMB is found when the screening coverage is 90% and the screening interval is 0.67 years (Fig. 2; the yellow dot in top centre panel). For WTPc=0.5 and pt=100%, the maximum mean NMB is also at the maximum screening coverage, but the higher treatment coverage (pt) indicates that the optimal screening interval is of 1.25 years. The optimal screening interval is the same for all values of the number of zero-detections, but the minimum NMB was found at za=1 and zr=1 (see accompanying app). It is notable that a very high WTP (3 times the GDP per capita) lends strong support for shorter screening intervals, favouring screenings in a village multiple times a year.
Second, and turning the attention from the active screening interval to the coverage, we found that in terms of NMB, the screening coverage has an inverse relationship with the treatment coverage under passive surveillance (pt). When pt=100%, the assumption is that all infections are eventually treated, implying no loss of life, which would otherwise be a large component of the change in NMB. Thus, under the assumption of a high pt, active screening strategies with low coverage will be preferable, indicating that high costs of screening implementation will hardly be justified by DALYs averted, as passive surveillance is already very effective (Fig. 2). In contrast, under an assumption of a lower pt, high active screening coverage is needed to compensate for lower treatment coverage in passive surveillance.

Sensitivity analysis of village characteristics and maximum net monetary benefits

We present the active screening strategy that gives the maximum mean NMB for a range of WTP values, examining the role of the treatment coverage under passive surveillance, the village population size, and the endemicity status of the village. To do this, we apply costs (see Additional file 1: Table S3) to the mean simulation outputs to see which strategy provides the largest NMB. Each line in Fig. 3a–c shows the value of c, t and za that together give the optimal strategy for given values of pt and WTP. For instance, assuming that WTPc=0.5 and pt=27%, the maximum NMB is obtained for c=90%, t=0.67 years, and za=1 (Fig. 3a–c). Figure 3d–f considers the same results for villages of different sizes (NH) and with different initial conditions of the simulation (endemic, disease-free, and endemic with importations), all with pt=27%. We fix zr=1 for all simulations.
Screening coverage, c, is optimal at 0% (not doing any screening) or at a very high coverage (the maximum of 90%) (Fig. 3a). For pt=27%, active screening at the maximum coverage is optimal for WTPc>0.02 (Fig. 3a). This means if there is no WTP to avert DALYs (the decision-maker wants to remain cost-neutral), it is best not to incur any screening costs, since the NMB will be negative, however, if the WTP is above threshold 0.02 of GDP per capita, it is optimal to screen entire village populations to reduce the prevalence and prevent further transmission. The threshold WTP where maximum screening coverage is optimal is also influenced by pt; the WTP threshold decreases for larger values of pt (above 27%) and active screening campaigns are always optimal for higher pt values. Therefore, at high pt values (treatment coverage), the additional costs of active screening are justified in order to shorten disease duration and expedite elimination (recovering screening costs via averted treatment costs).
The optimal screening interval, t, and the number of active zero-detection before screening cessation are more sensitive to the WTP, but have similar patterns across values of treatment coverage (pt). The optimal screening interval, t, decreases with increasing WTP, since DALYs are valued more highly and more frequent screening averts more DALYs (Fig. 3b). We also show that for any value of pt, the screening interval must be two years or shorter, typically approximately annually. For most WTP values, a single active zero-detection is enough to justify cessation of active screening, but we note that if the funder is willing to pay more, there is a benefit in repeated active zero-detection campaigns before cessation in order to ensure no resurgence of transmission (Fig. 3c). To consider the full range of pt values a heatmap of the change in cost with respect to both pt and WTP is given in Additional file 1: Figure S8.
Additionally, we have considered three other scenarios: a smaller village population NH=250 at endemic equilibrium; a disease-free population starting with a single infection rather than endemic equilibrium, therefore mimicking a local post-elimination reintroduction of the infection; and a population with a small chance of an imported infection (Fig. 3d–f). For scenarios with the population size NH=1000, the results are qualitatively similar: lower active screening coverage is optimal when there are fewer infections (due to the single reintroduction). For a smaller population size NH=250, it is more effective to have a shorter screening interval and more campaigns that yield active zero-detections to ensure local elimination, since the cost of active screening is smaller when there are fewer people to screen. When there is a small rate of importation of infection, the higher probability of sustaining local infection means that a higher number of active zero-detections za are optimal for any given WTP, and therefore active screening must continue for a longer period of time.

Limiting analysis to practical strategies

According to other literature, a high coverage in active screening with a minimum number of visits is desirable [78], which agrees with our results (Fig. 3). However, unlike the screening interval and the number of active zero-detections before cessation, which can be designated by district managers, it is not always possible to achieve a desired screening coverage by either decree or investment because screening coverage depends on the availability and consent of the population [32]. In fact, attendance at active screening is often low [79]; for instance, in Kwamouth during 2000–2016, a median screening coverage of 55% was achieved for all village-level active screenings taken from the WHO HAT Atlas [40, 41] (see Additional file 1: Figure S2).
Therefore, since a high screening coverage cannot be guaranteed, we optimise active screening when we have imposed a maximum on the screening coverage consistent with historic (obtainable) coverage in DRC. A higher maximum level of screening coverage allows for a large screening interval and a small number of zero-detections before cessation of active screening. For the very low minimum screening coverage of 5%, the optimum is screening four times a year t=0.25 and five zero-detections to stop (za=5), whilst for a high coverage, we see the expected result of t≈1 year and za=1 (Fig. 4). For the median screening coverage in Kwamouth of 55%, the optimal strategy is an active screening every four months, with two active zero-detection required for cessation. A lower screening coverage can be compensated for by an increase in screening frequency thereby reducing the screening interval t.

Cost-effectiveness of realistic strategies

Whilst we have determined which strategy, on average, maximises NMB for achievable levels of screening coverage, we now consider the cost-effectiveness of select strategies, restricting the number of strategies under consideration to a smaller number of options. For this process, we have selected seven options: doing no active screening and six realistic proposal schemes for active screening including biennial and annual screening with different cessation criteria. These active screening strategies are shown in Table 3. We assume zr=1, pt=27% and NH=1,000, and we initialise simulations with conditions consistent with endemic equilibrium.
Table 3
Active screening strategies considered in the probability of cost-effectiveness calculations
No.
Strategy
Screening coverage, c (%)
Screening interval, t (years)
Active zero- detections, za
Total cost (<DOLLAR/>)
Total DALYs
ACER (<DOLLAR/>/DALY)
ICER (<DOLLAR/>/DALY)
1
Passive surveillance only1
0
N/A
N/A
25754 [12267, 40807]
2488.8 [1207.8, 3912.6]
Minimum cost
Minimum cost
2
Biennial screening with one zero for cessation
55
2
1
42517 [23546, 62968]
1338.9 [437.8,1755.7]
14.6
14.62
3
Biennial screening with two zeros for cessation
55
2
2
43066 [24432, 63133]
1339.4 [436.3,1755.5]
15.1
Dominated
4
Biennial screening with three zeros for cessation
55
2
3
43501 [25092, 63266]
1340.1 [434.8,1756.5]
15.4
Dominated
5
Annual screening with one zero for cessation
55
1
1
48885 [26628, 72263]
1027.9 [570.3, 2262.7]
15.8
20.43
6
Annual screening with two zeros for cessation
55
1
2
49571 [27896, 72428]
1027.7 [570.6, 2264.3]
16.3
2501.44
7
Annual screening with three zeros for cessation
55
1
3
50163 [28670, 72806]
1027.4 [572.9, 2261.9]
16.7
2772.35
1The comparator strategy. 2Relative to Strategy 1. 3Relative to Strategy 2. 4Relative to Strategy 5. 5Relative to Strategy 6.
We show the mean total cost (to nearest dollar) and the total number of DALYs (to the nearest 0.1 DALYs) for each strategy with the 95% prediction intervals across all stochastic realisations. The ACER is the change in cost over the change in DALYs averted as compared to the baseline strategy, whilst the ICER is compared to the next best strategy (given in the table footnotes). Costs are denominated in 2018 US dollars
For our comparator strategy (passive surveillance only) the total cost of implementation is the cost of testing and treating self-presenting individuals infected with gHAT. As previously stated, we do not include the fixed costs of continually operating a passive surveillance network, as we assume that implementing a strategy does not change this cost. Thus, Table 3 shows the average cost of only treating self-presenting patients is <DOLLAR/>25,754 with 2488.8 DALYs. Since we are considering this our baseline strategy, zero DALYs are averted from this process.
By employing active screening the total costs increase to the benefit of health outcomes; annual screening costs more than biennial screening, but a correspondingly larger number of DALYs are averted under strategies that use annual screening. On the other hand, increasing the number of active zero-detections increases costs but yields few additional DALYs under a regiment of annual screening and even fewer DALYs under biennial screening. Given the 95% prediction intervals for the total DALYs averted for varying just the active zero-detections greatly overlap, there is little basis on which to choose between these strategies other than lowering costs, but the screening interval is much more significant in terms of health benefits conferred (Table 3).
We calculate the average cost-effectiveness ratio (ACER) as the ratio of the change in cost to change in DALYs averted relative to the comparator strategy, whilst the incremental average cost-effectiveness ratio (ICER) is the ratio of the change in cost to change in DALYs averted relative to the next best option (see Table 3). The ICER is the conventional metric for cost-effectiveness: a strategy is cost-effective compared to the next best strategy if ICER < WTP. Active screening at 55% coverage is cost-effective at extremely low WTP values (<DOLLAR/>14–17 per DALY averted), and the costs-per-DALY of biennial and annual screening strategies are so similar as to suggest that there is little loss in efficiency (few diminishing returns) in undertaking more frequent (yearly) campaigns. Notably, however, a higher WTP (<DOLLAR/>2501 per DALY) would be needed to support the choice of strategies with higher values of za (multiple active zero-detections), but such strategies should not be implemented at the expense of longer screening intervals. Strategies with higher values of za are primarily payment for certainty that transmission chains have been broken, rather purchasing any substantial health burden averted (in terms of DALYs).

Cost-effectiveness analysis in the presence of parameter uncertainty

Not every village will experience gHAT infection as depicted by the mean infection profile. Hence, we aim to account for uncertainty and present the probability that a strategy is cost-effective. Using the full range of possibilities for the infection dynamics is particularly important for gHAT infection in a village as we know there is potential for large differences between seemingly identical villages, due to the focal nature of the infection [8]. Therefore, we have simulated the infection dynamics of each strategy one million times to compare how the costs and number of DALYs averted can vary.
When there is no active screening, the variations in the cost and DALYs incurred arises from uncertainty in the transmission model (since cost parameters are held constant). By the same token, costs and DALYs are positively correlated because both arise from transmission, passive detection and treatment. The more infections there are in the village, the more treatments will be performed, increasing costs and incurring DALYs. Inversely, when there are few infections, DALYs and costs are lower. Moreover, the correlation between DALYs and costs is not perfect, there is large variation in both measures (Fig. 5a).
There is a similar pattern when active screening exists, but the range of introduced costs and the number of occurring treatments increases, expanding the variance in outcomes and weakening the correlation between costs and DALYs. However, reducing the screening interval both increases the costs and reduces the number of DALYs incurred, all other things held equal. Results for alternative numbers of zero-detections remain marginal over all parameter values (Fig. 5a). There are significant differences in the outcomes of strategies with different screening intervals, but we reiterate that the differences are robust to different numbers of active zero-detections (Table 3 and Additional file 1: Figure S3).
We have calculated the probability a strategy is cost-effective by taking the proportion of our one million simulations for each strategy that has the largest NMB at each specific value of WTP (Fig. 5b), thereby producing cost-effectiveness acceptability curves (CEACs) [80]. The strategy with no active screening has the highest probability of being cost-effective for low WTP; however, the probability is approximately 50% for the lowest WTP (at cost-neutral values), indicating that performing any active screening might still be cost-effective. The strategy with no active screening has negligible probability of being the cost-effective (<1%) for approximately WTPc>0.23. For the highest WTP values, strategy 7 (annual screening with three zero-detections), has the highest probability, with similar probabilities for the other strategies with annual screening. Given the probability of being cost-effective for high WTP is so similar for strategies 5, 6 and 7, it is difficult to make a recommendation about which is better, and so the most cautious strategy s should likely be favoured, given the minimal change in costs.
It is notable that for certain values of WTP, the strategy with the highest probability of cost-effectiveness does not always correspond with the preferred strategy according to the ICER. These calculations are demonstrated by the cost-effectiveness acceptability frontier (CEAF), which is shown as the shaded and numbered background (Fig. 5b). The CEAF is the optimal strategy according to the maximum expected NMB (rather than the highest probability of the NMB). Discrepancies between the highest mean NMB and the probability of the highest NMB occur because of asymmetric distributions in our parameters, but it is the CEAF which is used to provide strategy recommendations for a given WTP threshold for risk-neutral decision-makers [81].
In the lower-prevalence health zone of Mosango (Additional file 1: Figure S3) we find similar results, with a recommendation for annual screening over biennial screening at moderate WTP values or no active screening at lower WTP values.

Discussion

To achieve the goal of eliminating gHAT it is useful to have robust models that can inform policy makers about the potential of different intervention strategies [82]. As such, we have followed the five principles of the Neglected Tropical Diseases Modelling Consortium (see Additional file 1: Table S7), which were proposed to improve the quality of communication between modellers and stakeholders [58]. Furthermore, the addition of economic analysis will further develop the use of this work, as to not only evaluate which strategies are able to decrease in infection in the population, but which are cost-effective.
We have presented a stochastic model for individual villages that demonstrates how active screening should be considered, by determining costs of implementing the screening for different screening coverage levels c, screening intervals t, and the number of zero-detections observed to stop screening za and zr. Using WTPc=0.5 we find on average that ideally screening would be done approximately yearly with maximal screening coverage and ceased when no infection is found in a single screening (c=90%, t=0.67 years, za=1) (Fig. 3). Whilst the optimum for the screening interval is found to be 0.67 years, if there is a higher proportion of infection eventually treated in the population than the assumed pt=27%, the optimal interval is larger (1.25 years for pt=100%). Practically these intervals might be difficult to implement, so we believe that the current work supports the implementation of yearly screening. These results have been specifically calibrated to the high-endemicity health zone of Kwamouth, DRC, however similar results for the lower-prevalence health zone of Mosango, DRC (Additional file 1: Figure S3) support that our recommendations are generalisable to other regions with low- to high-endemicity (further analysis would be required to apply these results to very low-endemicity regions or regions with historically very low screening coverage). It is noted that such high screening coverage will rarely be able to be achieved, and so multiple visits where no infection is observed may be necessary to optimise control, although the model shows no significant differences in cost-effectiveness. This is in line with WHO guidelines of annual active screenings until there have been three consecutive years of no new cases, followed by a further screening with no cases three years after cessation of activities [5].
In particular, we note that whilst we assumed that reactive screening should immediately resume upon identification of an infection through passive surveillance, the time interval for reactive screening to begin has little effect on the results (see Additional file 1: Figure S6). Therefore, we conclude that practical concerns about the feasibility of reactive screening do not impact our conclusions, as long as reactive surveillance is deployed within two years of finding an new case through passive surveillance.
In fact, the choice of a low za has a high probability of triggering reactive screening (>70%), and therefore, we recommend that logistics for reactive screening are put in place (see Additional file 1: Figure S5). The time-horizon of 30 years is sufficient in the village context to capture the dynamics; when we expanded the horizon to 100 years, we found that roughly 99.1% of costs and 99.8% of DALYs are attributable to the first 30 years (see Additional file 1: Figure S7).
As new treatments and active screening modes are introduced, the costs of the model will change, however, the biggest effect is that of the number of DALYs averted, assuming the WTP threshold is set to a reasonable level. Details of the variation in NMB for different screening diagnostics and medical treatments can be found in Additional file 1: Figure S9.
We also note that from the perspective of a single village (and from the perspective of a risk-neutral payer), we do not put any weight on local elimination beyond that captured by expected DALYs averted, favouring an optimal screening strategy that terminates the programme after a single active zero-detection (za=1), rather than repeated zero-detections to ensure elimination. On the other hand, when it is assumed that a village is susceptible to importations of infection, we find that more active zero-detections are required to maximise the NMB (Fig. 3f). Other work has shown that at least three zero-detections for villages of this size (NH=1000) [26] to ensure elimination, but it is unclear how much monetary value we should attribute to meeting EOT targets.
Our finding that a single zero-detection is optimal in Fig. 3 is particularly notable when the screening coverage c is at the maximum (90%). In this case, there is higher confidence that local gHAT elimination has been achieved, as almost all the population is screened and there are no cases left to be detected, and even if infection temporarily persists after this, there is a large probability it will die out due to stochastic fade out [26]. However, a regular 90% coverage is probably unfeasible, and more realistic screening coverage will require more zero-detections to terminate active screening (Fig. 4).
We note that there may be also be additional costs in restarting active screening as reactive screening, in particular if regional cessation results in disbanded trained mobile teams. We have not accounted for this in our model, but it may lend support to a higher number of active zero-detections, which lower the probability of reactive screening once routine active surveillance has ceased (see Additional file 1: Figure S5). We cannot make a recommendation for the number of reactive zero-detections as the impact is negligible on the cost-effectiveness (even less so than the active zero-detections) and the effect is completely outweighed by the stochasticity of the infection dynamics (see Additional file 1: Figure S6).
Whilst many other diseases have established procedures for active case finding and evaluated cost-effectiveness (i.e. tuberculosis) few have done it for elimination and no studies have evaluated active screening properties with this level of detail. Bessell et al. [11] found that RDTs can be cost-effective; Sutherland et al. [54] took active screening programme properties for granted and instead focused on the combination of active screening, passive surveillance, and vector control. Therefore, this is the first cost-effectiveness paper that examines in detail the relative efficiency of active screening strategies. Furthermore, we have provided the tools for the reader to adapt the analysis to their specific chosen costs (see accompanying app).
Unsurprisingly, we find that a big factor in choosing a strategy to implement is how much the programme funder, ministry of health or external donor is willing to pay to avert an additional DALY beyond other acceptable configurations of the me. WTP is not a metric about the total cost of the me, it is a metric of comparative efficiency, considering incremental costs and incremental effects between two or more strategies. To calculate what WTP gHAT programmes were acting on in the past, one would have to know what alternative strategies they were considering, which is beyond the scope of our current work. In addition, contributions to gHAT programmes are complicated, since much of the activity has historically been funded by donors; indeed, without external funding there would be substantial harm to the programme [83]. Therefore, we present our results across a range of WTP values. We have used a WTP value of 0.5 of the GDP per capita of the DRC (WTPc=0.5), which is commonly used in the literature [72, 84], but note there may be a higher WTP to achieve the additional aim of gHAT elimination.
Future research is warranted to evaluate the specific characteristics of each village, how villages and health zones (or districts) share costs and the impact it makes on relative efficiency. Moreover, the risk of importation, the impact of potential sero-negative skin-infected cases, and the risk of animal reservoirs would have to be further explored in in-depth epidemiological modelling.

Conclusions

Using a dynamic cost-effectiveness framework we have performed analysis to examine the optimal use of medical resources for strategies against gHAT as it approaches the end-game. With a limited number of active screening teams and resources for them to carry out their duties, it is important to have guidelines that optimise their activities with the aim of driving towards elimination. We considered a range of different active screening interventions, including changing the coverage, frequency and cessation criterion of screening, on top of a baseline passive surveillance system. The results indicate that active screening is effective in reducing case numbers and hence the infection in the population, with approximately annual screening representing good use of resources and being cost-effective at very low WTP (> <DOLLAR/>20.4/DALY averted) when realistic coverage of 55% was assumed. Biennial screening at the same coverage each visit would avert fewer DALYs at a slightly lower cost and was only cost-effective for a narrow range of WTP values (<DOLLAR/>14.6–20.4). The calculated costs and DALYs averted were very similar for all the cessation criteria considered here (one, two or three years of zero cases before stopping active screening), however the additional information gained about progress towards elimination of transmission, leads us to suggest cessation after three years of zeros is appropriate. We recommend that active screening should be carried out annually with cessation after three years of detecting no cases for a moderate-to high-endemicity health zone in the DRC—in line with current WHO guidance.

Acknowledgements

Not applicable.

Declarations

Not applicable.
Not applicable.

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.
Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visithttp://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​. The Creative Commons Public Domain Dedication waiver (http://​creativecommons.​org/​publicdomain/​zero/​1.​0/​) applies to the data made available in this article, unless otherwise stated in a credit line to the data.

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Anhänge

Supplementary Information

Additional file 1 Figures S1–S10 and Tables S1–S7. Supporting information for the manuscript including further details of the gHAT modelling, explanations and derivations of all net monetary benefit parameters, a short analysis of a different health zone, details on reactive screening, some additional results, and a table of how we satisfied the five principles of the Neglected Tropical Diseases Modelling Consortium. Figure S1 – Schematic of the compartmental model for gHAT infection dynamics in humans (low- and high-risk) and tsetse. Figure S2 – Histograms of screening coverage for (A) Kwamouth and (B) Mosango. Figure S3 – The cost-effectiveness of active screening strategies for the health zone of Mosango. Figure S4 – The effect of the number of zero-detections in reactive screening on the cost effective acceptability curves (CEACs). Figure S5 – Active and reactive screenings information. Figure S6 – The time interval between observing a passive detection and resuming reactive screening for different values of active zero-detections. Figure S7 – Distributions of (A) the change in cost of an active screening strategy and (B) the number of DALYs averted for 30- and 100-year time-horizons. Figure S8 – Theoretical optimum strategy for mean simulation of infection dynamics given WTP and pt. Figure S9 – Mean change in costs relative to the assumed interventions for a village with 55% screening coverage annually with 3 zero-detections. Figure S10 – Linear fits through the results of different active screening strategies from Fig. 5. Table S1 – The transition rates of the Markov-chain gHAT-infection model and additional ordinary differential equation component of the model. Table S2 – Parameter notation and values for the gHAT infection model. Table S3 – Net monetary benefit parameters that determine our manuscript parameters. Table S4 – Proportion of people receiving each type of treatment. Table S5 – Formulation of manuscript parameters from cost data. Table S6 – The values that determine the linear fits for each strategy in Figure S10. Table S7 – PRIME-NTD criteria fulfillment.
Literatur
2.
Zurück zum Zitat Franco JR, Cecchi G, Priotto G, Paone M, Diarra A, Grout L, Simarro PP, Zhao W, Argaw D. Monitoring the elimination of human african trypanosomiasis at continental and country level: Update to 2018. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2020; 14(5):0008261.CrossRef Franco JR, Cecchi G, Priotto G, Paone M, Diarra A, Grout L, Simarro PP, Zhao W, Argaw D. Monitoring the elimination of human african trypanosomiasis at continental and country level: Update to 2018. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2020; 14(5):0008261.CrossRef
3.
Zurück zum Zitat Jamonneau V, Ilboudo H, Kaboré J, Kaba D, Koffi M, Solano P, Garcia A, Courtin D, Laveissière C, Lingue K, et al. Untreated human infections by trypanosoma brucei gambiense are not 100% fatal. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2012; 6(6):1691.CrossRef Jamonneau V, Ilboudo H, Kaboré J, Kaba D, Koffi M, Solano P, Garcia A, Courtin D, Laveissière C, Lingue K, et al. Untreated human infections by trypanosoma brucei gambiense are not 100% fatal. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2012; 6(6):1691.CrossRef
5.
Zurück zum Zitat World Health Organization. Control and surveillance of human African trypanosomiasis. World Health Organ Tech Rep Ser. 2013; (984):1–237. PMID: 24552089. World Health Organization. Control and surveillance of human African trypanosomiasis. World Health Organ Tech Rep Ser. 2013; (984):1–237. PMID: 24552089.
6.
Zurück zum Zitat Franco J, Simarro P, Diarra A, Ruiz-Postigo J, Jannin J. The journey towards elimination of gambiense human african trypanosomiasis: not far, nor easy. Parasitology. 2014; 141(6):748–60.PubMedCrossRef Franco J, Simarro P, Diarra A, Ruiz-Postigo J, Jannin J. The journey towards elimination of gambiense human african trypanosomiasis: not far, nor easy. Parasitology. 2014; 141(6):748–60.PubMedCrossRef
7.
Zurück zum Zitat Robays J, Bilengue MMC, Stuyft P. V. d., Boelaert M. The effectiveness of active population screening and treatment for sleeping sickness control in the democratic republic of congo. Trop Med Int Health. 2004; 9(5):542–50.PubMedCrossRef Robays J, Bilengue MMC, Stuyft P. V. d., Boelaert M. The effectiveness of active population screening and treatment for sleeping sickness control in the democratic republic of congo. Trop Med Int Health. 2004; 9(5):542–50.PubMedCrossRef
8.
Zurück zum Zitat Büscher P, Cecchi G, Jamonneau V, Priotto G. Human African trypanosomiasis. Lancet. 2017; 390(10110):2397–409.PubMedCrossRef Büscher P, Cecchi G, Jamonneau V, Priotto G. Human African trypanosomiasis. Lancet. 2017; 390(10110):2397–409.PubMedCrossRef
9.
Zurück zum Zitat Lumbala C, Simarro PP, Cecchi G, Paone M, Franco JR, Mesu VKBK, Makabuza J, Diarra A, Chansy S, Priotto G, et al. Human african trypanosomiasis in the democratic republic of the congo: disease distribution and risk. Int J Health Geogr. 2015; 14(1):20.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Lumbala C, Simarro PP, Cecchi G, Paone M, Franco JR, Mesu VKBK, Makabuza J, Diarra A, Chansy S, Priotto G, et al. Human african trypanosomiasis in the democratic republic of the congo: disease distribution and risk. Int J Health Geogr. 2015; 14(1):20.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
10.
Zurück zum Zitat Magnus E, Van Meirvenne N, Vervoort T, Le Ray D, Wéry M, Others. Use of freeze-dried trypanosomes in the indirect fluorescent antibody test for the serodiagnosis of sleeping sickness. Ann Soc Belg Méd Trop. 1978; 58:103–9.PubMed Magnus E, Van Meirvenne N, Vervoort T, Le Ray D, Wéry M, Others. Use of freeze-dried trypanosomes in the indirect fluorescent antibody test for the serodiagnosis of sleeping sickness. Ann Soc Belg Méd Trop. 1978; 58:103–9.PubMed
11.
Zurück zum Zitat Bessell PR, Lumbala C, Lutumba P, Baloji S, Bieler S, Ndung’u JM. Cost-effectiveness of using a rapid diagnostic test to screen for human african trypanosomiasis in the democratic republic of the congo. PLoS ONE. 2018; 13(9):e0204335.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Bessell PR, Lumbala C, Lutumba P, Baloji S, Bieler S, Ndung’u JM. Cost-effectiveness of using a rapid diagnostic test to screen for human african trypanosomiasis in the democratic republic of the congo. PLoS ONE. 2018; 13(9):e0204335.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
12.
Zurück zum Zitat Wamboga C, Matovu E, Bessell PR, Picado A, Biéler S, Ndung’u JM. Enhanced passive screening and diagnosis for gambiense human african trypanosomiasis in north-western uganda–moving towards elimination. PLoS ONE. 2017; 12(10):e0186429.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Wamboga C, Matovu E, Bessell PR, Picado A, Biéler S, Ndung’u JM. Enhanced passive screening and diagnosis for gambiense human african trypanosomiasis in north-western uganda–moving towards elimination. PLoS ONE. 2017; 12(10):e0186429.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
13.
Zurück zum Zitat Lee SJ, Palmer JJ. Integrating innovations: a qualitative analysis of referral non-completion among rapid diagnostic test-positive patients in uganda’s human african trypanosomiasis elimination programme. Infect Dis Poverty. 2018; 7(1):1–16.CrossRef Lee SJ, Palmer JJ. Integrating innovations: a qualitative analysis of referral non-completion among rapid diagnostic test-positive patients in uganda’s human african trypanosomiasis elimination programme. Infect Dis Poverty. 2018; 7(1):1–16.CrossRef
14.
Zurück zum Zitat Mumba Ngoyi D, Menten J, Pyana PP, Büscher P, Lejon V. Stage determination in sleeping sickness: Comparison of two cell counting and two parasite detection techniques. Trop Medi Int Health. 2013; 18(6):778–82.CrossRef Mumba Ngoyi D, Menten J, Pyana PP, Büscher P, Lejon V. Stage determination in sleeping sickness: Comparison of two cell counting and two parasite detection techniques. Trop Medi Int Health. 2013; 18(6):778–82.CrossRef
15.
Zurück zum Zitat Chappuis F. Oral fexinidazole for human african trypanosomiasis. The Lancet. 2018; 391(10116):100–2.CrossRef Chappuis F. Oral fexinidazole for human african trypanosomiasis. The Lancet. 2018; 391(10116):100–2.CrossRef
16.
Zurück zum Zitat WHO interim guidelines for the treatment of gambiense human African trypanosomiasis. Geneva: World Health Organization; 2019. PMID: 31449367. WHO interim guidelines for the treatment of gambiense human African trypanosomiasis. Geneva: World Health Organization; 2019. PMID: 31449367.
17.
Zurück zum Zitat Koffi M, N’Djetchi M, Ilboudo H, Kaba D, Coulibaly B, N’Gouan E, Kouakou L, Bucheton B, Solano P, Courtin F, et al. A targeted door-to-door strategy for sleeping sickness detection in low-prevalence settings in Côte d’Ivoire. Parasite. 2016; 23:51.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Koffi M, N’Djetchi M, Ilboudo H, Kaba D, Coulibaly B, N’Gouan E, Kouakou L, Bucheton B, Solano P, Courtin F, et al. A targeted door-to-door strategy for sleeping sickness detection in low-prevalence settings in Côte d’Ivoire. Parasite. 2016; 23:51.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
18.
Zurück zum Zitat Mitashi P, Hasker E, Mbo F, Van Geertruyden J, Kaswa M, Lumbala C, Boelaert M, Lutumb a. P.Integration of diagnosis and treatment of sleeping sickness in primary healthcare facilities in the democratic republic of the congo. Trop Med Int Health. 2015; 20(1):98–105.PubMedCrossRef Mitashi P, Hasker E, Mbo F, Van Geertruyden J, Kaswa M, Lumbala C, Boelaert M, Lutumb a. P.Integration of diagnosis and treatment of sleeping sickness in primary healthcare facilities in the democratic republic of the congo. Trop Med Int Health. 2015; 20(1):98–105.PubMedCrossRef
19.
Zurück zum Zitat Van Nieuwenhove S. Present strategies in the treatment of human African trypanosomiasis. In: Progress in Human African Trypanosomiasis, Sleeping Sickness. Paris: Springer: 1999. p. 253–80. Van Nieuwenhove S. Present strategies in the treatment of human African trypanosomiasis. In: Progress in Human African Trypanosomiasis, Sleeping Sickness. Paris: Springer: 1999. p. 253–80.
20.
Zurück zum Zitat Simarro P, Franco J, Asumu PN. Has the focus of human African trypanosomiasis in Luba, Equatorial Guinea been eradicated?. Med Trop revue du Corps de sante colonial. 2001; 61(4-5):441–4. Simarro P, Franco J, Asumu PN. Has the focus of human African trypanosomiasis in Luba, Equatorial Guinea been eradicated?. Med Trop revue du Corps de sante colonial. 2001; 61(4-5):441–4.
21.
Zurück zum Zitat Pandey A, Atkins KE, Bucheton B, Camara M, Aksoy S, Galvani AP, Ndeffo-Mbah ML. Evaluating long-term effectiveness of sleeping sickness control measures in Guinea. Parasites Vectors. 2015; 8(1):550.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Pandey A, Atkins KE, Bucheton B, Camara M, Aksoy S, Galvani AP, Ndeffo-Mbah ML. Evaluating long-term effectiveness of sleeping sickness control measures in Guinea. Parasites Vectors. 2015; 8(1):550.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
22.
Zurück zum Zitat Rock KS, Torr SJ, Lumbala C, Keeling MJ. Quantitative evaluation of the strategy to eliminate human African trypanosomiasis in the DRC. Parasites Vectors. 2015; 8(1):532.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Rock KS, Torr SJ, Lumbala C, Keeling MJ. Quantitative evaluation of the strategy to eliminate human African trypanosomiasis in the DRC. Parasites Vectors. 2015; 8(1):532.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
23.
Zurück zum Zitat De Vries H, Wagelmans AP, Hasker E, Lumbala C, Lutumba P, De Vlas SJ, van de Klundert J. Forecasting human african trypanosomiasis prevalences from population screening data using continuous time models. PLoS Comput Biol. 2016; 12(9):e1005103.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef De Vries H, Wagelmans AP, Hasker E, Lumbala C, Lutumba P, De Vlas SJ, van de Klundert J. Forecasting human african trypanosomiasis prevalences from population screening data using continuous time models. PLoS Comput Biol. 2016; 12(9):e1005103.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
24.
Zurück zum Zitat Rock KS, Torr SJ, Lumbala C, Keeling MJ. Predicting the impact of intervention strategies for sleeping sickness in two high-endemicity health zones of the Democratic Republic of Congo. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2017; 11:0005162.CrossRef Rock KS, Torr SJ, Lumbala C, Keeling MJ. Predicting the impact of intervention strategies for sleeping sickness in two high-endemicity health zones of the Democratic Republic of Congo. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2017; 11:0005162.CrossRef
25.
Zurück zum Zitat Mahamat MH, Peka M, Rayaisse J. -b., Rock KS, Toko MA, Darnas J, Brahim GM, Alkatib AB, Yoni W, Tirados I, Courtin F, Brand SPC, Nersy C, Alfaroukh O, Torr SJ, Lehane MJ, Solano P. Adding tsetse control to medical activities contributes to decreasing transmission of sleeping sickness in the Mandoul focus (Chad). PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2017; 11(7):0005792.CrossRef Mahamat MH, Peka M, Rayaisse J. -b., Rock KS, Toko MA, Darnas J, Brahim GM, Alkatib AB, Yoni W, Tirados I, Courtin F, Brand SPC, Nersy C, Alfaroukh O, Torr SJ, Lehane MJ, Solano P. Adding tsetse control to medical activities contributes to decreasing transmission of sleeping sickness in the Mandoul focus (Chad). PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2017; 11(7):0005792.CrossRef
26.
Zurück zum Zitat Davis CN, Rock KS, Miaka EM, Keeling MJ. Village-scale persistence and elimination of gambiense human african trypanosomiasis. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2019; 13(10):e0007838.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Davis CN, Rock KS, Miaka EM, Keeling MJ. Village-scale persistence and elimination of gambiense human african trypanosomiasis. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2019; 13(10):e0007838.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
27.
Zurück zum Zitat Ndeffo-Mbah ML, Pandey A, Atkins KE, Aksoy S, Galvani AP. The impact of vector migration on the effectiveness of strategies to control gambiense human african trypanosomiasis. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2019; 13(12):e0007903.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Ndeffo-Mbah ML, Pandey A, Atkins KE, Aksoy S, Galvani AP. The impact of vector migration on the effectiveness of strategies to control gambiense human african trypanosomiasis. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2019; 13(12):e0007903.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
28.
Zurück zum Zitat Castaño MS, Ndeffo-Mbah ML, Rock KS, Palmer C, Knock E, Miaka EM, Ndung’u JM, Torr S, Verlé P, Spencer SE, et al. Assessing the impact of aggregating disease stage data in model predictions of human african trypanosomiasis transmission and control activities in bandundu province (drc). PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2020; 14(1):0007976.CrossRef Castaño MS, Ndeffo-Mbah ML, Rock KS, Palmer C, Knock E, Miaka EM, Ndung’u JM, Torr S, Verlé P, Spencer SE, et al. Assessing the impact of aggregating disease stage data in model predictions of human african trypanosomiasis transmission and control activities in bandundu province (drc). PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2020; 14(1):0007976.CrossRef
29.
Zurück zum Zitat Huang C-I, Crump RE, Brown P, Spencer SE, Miaka EM, Shampa C, Keeling MJ, Rock KS. Shrinking the ghat map: identifying target regions for enhanced control of gambiense human african trypanosomiasis in the democratic republic of congo. medRxiv. 2020; 07(03):20145847. https://doi.org/10.1101/2020.07.03.20145847. Huang C-I, Crump RE, Brown P, Spencer SE, Miaka EM, Shampa C, Keeling MJ, Rock KS. Shrinking the ghat map: identifying target regions for enhanced control of gambiense human african trypanosomiasis in the democratic republic of congo. medRxiv. 2020; 07(03):20145847. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1101/​2020.​07.​03.​20145847.
32.
Zurück zum Zitat Mpanya A, Hendrickx D, Vuna M, Kanyinda A, Lumbala C, Tshilombo V, Mitashi P, Luboya O, Kande V, Boelaert M, Lefévre P, Lutumba P. Should I get screened for sleeping sickness? A qualitative study in Kasai province. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2012; 6(1):1467.CrossRef Mpanya A, Hendrickx D, Vuna M, Kanyinda A, Lumbala C, Tshilombo V, Mitashi P, Luboya O, Kande V, Boelaert M, Lefévre P, Lutumba P. Should I get screened for sleeping sickness? A qualitative study in Kasai province. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2012; 6(1):1467.CrossRef
33.
Zurück zum Zitat Rogers D. A general model for the African trypanosomiases. Parasitology. 1988; 97(1):193–212.PubMedCrossRef Rogers D. A general model for the African trypanosomiases. Parasitology. 1988; 97(1):193–212.PubMedCrossRef
34.
Zurück zum Zitat Checchi F, Filipe JAN, Haydon DT, Chandramohan D, Chappuis F. Estimates of the duration of the early and late stage of gambiense sleeping sickness. BMC Infect Dis. 2008; 8(1):16.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Checchi F, Filipe JAN, Haydon DT, Chandramohan D, Chappuis F. Estimates of the duration of the early and late stage of gambiense sleeping sickness. BMC Infect Dis. 2008; 8(1):16.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
35.
Zurück zum Zitat Checchi F, Funk S, Chandramohan D, Haydon DT, Chappuis F. Updated estimate of the duration of the meningo-encephalitic stage in gambiense human African trypanosomiasis. BMC Res Notes. 2015; 8(1):292.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Checchi F, Funk S, Chandramohan D, Haydon DT, Chappuis F. Updated estimate of the duration of the meningo-encephalitic stage in gambiense human African trypanosomiasis. BMC Res Notes. 2015; 8(1):292.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
36.
Zurück zum Zitat Davis S, Aksoy S, Galvani A. A global sensitivity analysis for African sleeping sickness. Parasitology. 2011; 138(4):516–26.PubMedCrossRef Davis S, Aksoy S, Galvani A. A global sensitivity analysis for African sleeping sickness. Parasitology. 2011; 138(4):516–26.PubMedCrossRef
37.
Zurück zum Zitat Ravel S, Grébaut P, Cuisance D, Cuny G. Monitoring the developmental status of Trypanosoma brucei gambiense in the tsetse fly by means of PCR analysis of anal and saliva drops. Acta Trop. 2003; 88(2):161–5.PubMedCrossRef Ravel S, Grébaut P, Cuisance D, Cuny G. Monitoring the developmental status of Trypanosoma brucei gambiense in the tsetse fly by means of PCR analysis of anal and saliva drops. Acta Trop. 2003; 88(2):161–5.PubMedCrossRef
38.
Zurück zum Zitat Clausen P, Adeyemi I, Bauer B, Breloeer M, Salchow F, Staak C. Host preferences of tsetse (Diptera: Glossinidae) based on bloodmeal identifications. Med Vet Entomol. 1998; 12(2):168–80.CrossRef Clausen P, Adeyemi I, Bauer B, Breloeer M, Salchow F, Staak C. Host preferences of tsetse (Diptera: Glossinidae) based on bloodmeal identifications. Med Vet Entomol. 1998; 12(2):168–80.CrossRef
39.
Zurück zum Zitat Checchi F, Chappuis F, Karunakara U, Priotto G, Chandramohan D. Accuracy of five algorithms to diagnose gambiense human african trypanosomiasis. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2011; 5(7):e1233.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Checchi F, Chappuis F, Karunakara U, Priotto G, Chandramohan D. Accuracy of five algorithms to diagnose gambiense human african trypanosomiasis. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2011; 5(7):e1233.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
40.
Zurück zum Zitat Simarro PP, Cecchi G, Franco JR, Paone M, A D, Priotto G, R M, J J. Monitoring the progress towards the elimination of gambiense human African trypanosomiasis. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2015; 9(6):0003785.CrossRef Simarro PP, Cecchi G, Franco JR, Paone M, A D, Priotto G, R M, J J. Monitoring the progress towards the elimination of gambiense human African trypanosomiasis. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2015; 9(6):0003785.CrossRef
41.
Zurück zum Zitat Simarro PP, Cecchi G, Jannin JG. The Atlas of human African trypanosomiasis: a contribution to global mapping of neglected tropical diseases. Int J Health Geogr. 2010; 9:57.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Simarro PP, Cecchi G, Jannin JG. The Atlas of human African trypanosomiasis: a contribution to global mapping of neglected tropical diseases. Int J Health Geogr. 2010; 9:57.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
43.
Zurück zum Zitat Lutumba P, Makieya E, Shaw A, Meheus F, Boelaert M. Human african trypanosomiasis in a rural community, democratic republic of congo. Emerg Infect Dis. 2007; 13(2):248.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Lutumba P, Makieya E, Shaw A, Meheus F, Boelaert M. Human african trypanosomiasis in a rural community, democratic republic of congo. Emerg Infect Dis. 2007; 13(2):248.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
45.
Zurück zum Zitat Kyu HH, Abate D, Abate KH, Abay SM, Abbafati C, Abbasi N, Abbastabar H, Abd-Allah F, Abdela J, Abdelalim A, et al. Global, regional, and national disability-adjusted life-years (dalys) for 359 diseases and injuries and healthy life expectancy (hale) for 195 countries and territories, 1990–2017: a systematic analysis for the global burden of disease study 2017. Lancet. 2018; 392(10159):1859–922.CrossRef Kyu HH, Abate D, Abate KH, Abay SM, Abbafati C, Abbasi N, Abbastabar H, Abd-Allah F, Abdela J, Abdelalim A, et al. Global, regional, and national disability-adjusted life-years (dalys) for 359 diseases and injuries and healthy life expectancy (hale) for 195 countries and territories, 1990–2017: a systematic analysis for the global burden of disease study 2017. Lancet. 2018; 392(10159):1859–922.CrossRef
46.
Zurück zum Zitat Snijders R, Fukinsia A, Claeys Y, Mpanya A, Hasker E, Meheus F, Miaka EM, Boelaert M. Cost of a new method of active screening for human African trypanosomiasis in the Democratic Republic of the Congo. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2020; 14(12):0008832.CrossRef Snijders R, Fukinsia A, Claeys Y, Mpanya A, Hasker E, Meheus F, Miaka EM, Boelaert M. Cost of a new method of active screening for human African trypanosomiasis in the Democratic Republic of the Congo. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2020; 14(12):0008832.CrossRef
47.
Zurück zum Zitat Lutumba P, Meheus F, Robays J, Miaka C, Kande V, Büscher P, Dujardin B, Boelaert M. Cost-effectiveness of algorithms for confirmation test of human african trypanosomiasis. Emerg Infect Dis. 2007; 13(10):1484.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Lutumba P, Meheus F, Robays J, Miaka C, Kande V, Büscher P, Dujardin B, Boelaert M. Cost-effectiveness of algorithms for confirmation test of human african trypanosomiasis. Emerg Infect Dis. 2007; 13(10):1484.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
48.
Zurück zum Zitat Irurzun-Lopez M, Erondu NA, Djibo A, Griffiths U, Stuart JM, Fernandez K, Ronveaux O, Le Gargasson J-B, Gessner BD, Colombini A. The actual and potential costs of meningitis surveillance in the african meningitis belt: Results from chad and niger. Vaccine. 2016; 34(8):1133–8.PubMedCrossRef Irurzun-Lopez M, Erondu NA, Djibo A, Griffiths U, Stuart JM, Fernandez K, Ronveaux O, Le Gargasson J-B, Gessner BD, Colombini A. The actual and potential costs of meningitis surveillance in the african meningitis belt: Results from chad and niger. Vaccine. 2016; 34(8):1133–8.PubMedCrossRef
49.
Zurück zum Zitat Bertram MY, Stenberg K, Brindley C, Li J, Serje J, Watts R, Edejer TT-T. Disease control programme support costs: an update of who-choice methodology, price databases and quantity assumptions. Cost Eff Resour Allocation. 2017; 15(1):21.CrossRef Bertram MY, Stenberg K, Brindley C, Li J, Serje J, Watts R, Edejer TT-T. Disease control programme support costs: an update of who-choice methodology, price databases and quantity assumptions. Cost Eff Resour Allocation. 2017; 15(1):21.CrossRef
50.
Zurück zum Zitat Stenberg K, Lauer JA, Gkountouras G, Fitzpatrick C, Stanciole A. Econometric estimation of who-choice country-specific costs for inpatient and outpatient health service delivery. Cost Eff Resour Allocation. 2018; 16(1):11.CrossRef Stenberg K, Lauer JA, Gkountouras G, Fitzpatrick C, Stanciole A. Econometric estimation of who-choice country-specific costs for inpatient and outpatient health service delivery. Cost Eff Resour Allocation. 2018; 16(1):11.CrossRef
51.
Zurück zum Zitat Keating J, Yukich JO, Sutherland CS, Woods G, Tediosi F. Human African trypanosomiasis prevention, treatment and control costs: A systematic review. Acta Trop. 2015; 150:4–13.PubMedCrossRef Keating J, Yukich JO, Sutherland CS, Woods G, Tediosi F. Human African trypanosomiasis prevention, treatment and control costs: A systematic review. Acta Trop. 2015; 150:4–13.PubMedCrossRef
52.
Zurück zum Zitat Shaw A, Cattand P. Analytical tools for planning cost-effective surveillance in gambiense sleeping sickness. Med Trop revue du Corps de sante colonial. 2001; 61(4-5):412–21. Shaw A, Cattand P. Analytical tools for planning cost-effective surveillance in gambiense sleeping sickness. Med Trop revue du Corps de sante colonial. 2001; 61(4-5):412–21.
53.
Zurück zum Zitat Mesu VKBK, Kalonji WM, Bardonneau C, Mordt OV, Blesson S, Simon F, Delhomme S, Bernhard S, Kuziena W, Lubaki J-PF, et al. Oral fexinidazole for late-stage african trypanosoma brucei gambiense trypanosomiasis: a pivotal multicentre, randomised, non-inferiority trial. Lancet. 2018; 391(10116):144–54.PubMedCrossRef Mesu VKBK, Kalonji WM, Bardonneau C, Mordt OV, Blesson S, Simon F, Delhomme S, Bernhard S, Kuziena W, Lubaki J-PF, et al. Oral fexinidazole for late-stage african trypanosoma brucei gambiense trypanosomiasis: a pivotal multicentre, randomised, non-inferiority trial. Lancet. 2018; 391(10116):144–54.PubMedCrossRef
54.
Zurück zum Zitat Sutherland CS, Stone CM, Steinmann P, Tanner M, Tediosi F. Seeing beyond 2020: an economic evaluation of contemporary and emerging strategies for elimination of Trypanosoma brucei gambiense. Lancet Glob Health. 2017; 5(1):69–79.CrossRef Sutherland CS, Stone CM, Steinmann P, Tanner M, Tediosi F. Seeing beyond 2020: an economic evaluation of contemporary and emerging strategies for elimination of Trypanosoma brucei gambiense. Lancet Glob Health. 2017; 5(1):69–79.CrossRef
55.
Zurück zum Zitat Antillon M, Huang C-I, Crump RE, Brown PE, Snijders R, Miaka EM, Keeling MJ, Rock KS, Tediosi F. Economic evaluation of gambiense human African trypanosomiasis elimination campaigns in five distinct transmission settings in the Democratic Republic of Congo. medRxiv. 2020. 2020.08.25.20181982; https://doi.org/10.1101/2020.08.25.20181982. Antillon M, Huang C-I, Crump RE, Brown PE, Snijders R, Miaka EM, Keeling MJ, Rock KS, Tediosi F. Economic evaluation of gambiense human African trypanosomiasis elimination campaigns in five distinct transmission settings in the Democratic Republic of Congo. medRxiv. 2020. 2020.08.25.20181982; https://​doi.​org/​10.​1101/​2020.​08.​25.​20181982.
56.
Zurück zum Zitat Hackett F, Ford LB, Fevre E, Simarro P. Incorporating scale dependence in disease burden estimates: the case of human african trypanosomiasis in uganda. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2014; 8(2):e2704.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Hackett F, Ford LB, Fevre E, Simarro P. Incorporating scale dependence in disease burden estimates: the case of human african trypanosomiasis in uganda. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2014; 8(2):e2704.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
58.
Zurück zum Zitat Behrend MR, Basáñez M-G, Hamley JI, Porco TC, Stolk WA, Walker M, de Vlas SJ, NTD Modelling Consortium. Modelling for policy: The five principles of the neglected tropical diseases modelling consortium. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2020; 14(4):0008033.CrossRef Behrend MR, Basáñez M-G, Hamley JI, Porco TC, Stolk WA, Walker M, de Vlas SJ, NTD Modelling Consortium. Modelling for policy: The five principles of the neglected tropical diseases modelling consortium. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2020; 14(4):0008033.CrossRef
59.
Zurück zum Zitat Franco JR, Cecchi G, Priotto G, Paone M, Diarra A, Grout L, Simarro PP, Zhao W, Argaw D. Monitoring the elimination of human African trypanosomiasis: Update to 2016. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2018; 12(12):0006890.CrossRef Franco JR, Cecchi G, Priotto G, Paone M, Diarra A, Grout L, Simarro PP, Zhao W, Argaw D. Monitoring the elimination of human African trypanosomiasis: Update to 2016. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2018; 12(12):0006890.CrossRef
60.
Zurück zum Zitat Sutherland CS, Tediosi F. Is the elimination of sleeping sickness’ affordable? Who will pay the price? Assessing the financial burden for the elimination of human African trypanosomiasis Trypanosoma brucei gambiense in sub-Saharan Africa. BMJ Glob Health. 2019; 4(2):1–11.CrossRef Sutherland CS, Tediosi F. Is the elimination of sleeping sickness’ affordable? Who will pay the price? Assessing the financial burden for the elimination of human African trypanosomiasis Trypanosoma brucei gambiense in sub-Saharan Africa. BMJ Glob Health. 2019; 4(2):1–11.CrossRef
61.
Zurück zum Zitat Franco JR, Simarro PP, Diarra A, Jannin JG. Epidemiology of human african trypanosomiasis. Clin Epidemiol. 2014; 6:257.PubMedPubMedCentral Franco JR, Simarro PP, Diarra A, Jannin JG. Epidemiology of human african trypanosomiasis. Clin Epidemiol. 2014; 6:257.PubMedPubMedCentral
62.
Zurück zum Zitat Stone CM, Chitnis N. Implications of heterogeneous biting exposure and animal hosts on trypanosomiasis brucei gambiense transmission and control. PLoS Comput Biol. 2015; 11(10):1004514.CrossRef Stone CM, Chitnis N. Implications of heterogeneous biting exposure and animal hosts on trypanosomiasis brucei gambiense transmission and control. PLoS Comput Biol. 2015; 11(10):1004514.CrossRef
63.
Zurück zum Zitat Kennedy PG. Clinical features, diagnosis, and treatment of human african trypanosomiasis (sleeping sickness). Lancet Neurol. 2013; 12(2):186–94.PubMedCrossRef Kennedy PG. Clinical features, diagnosis, and treatment of human african trypanosomiasis (sleeping sickness). Lancet Neurol. 2013; 12(2):186–94.PubMedCrossRef
64.
65.
Zurück zum Zitat Stanton MC, Esterhuizen J, Tirados I, Betts H, Torr SJ. The development of high resolution maps of tsetse abundance to guide interventions against human African trypanosomiasis in northern Uganda. Parasites Vectors. 2018; 11(1):340.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Stanton MC, Esterhuizen J, Tirados I, Betts H, Torr SJ. The development of high resolution maps of tsetse abundance to guide interventions against human African trypanosomiasis in northern Uganda. Parasites Vectors. 2018; 11(1):340.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
66.
Zurück zum Zitat Castaño MS, Aliee M, Mwamba Miaka E, Keeling MJ, Chitnis N, Rock KS. Screening strategies for a sustainable endpoint for gambiense sleeping sickness. J Infect Dis. 2020; 221(Supplement_5):539–45.CrossRef Castaño MS, Aliee M, Mwamba Miaka E, Keeling MJ, Chitnis N, Rock KS. Screening strategies for a sustainable endpoint for gambiense sleeping sickness. J Infect Dis. 2020; 221(Supplement_5):539–45.CrossRef
67.
Zurück zum Zitat Steinmann P, Stone CM, Sutherland CS, Tanner M, Tediosi F. Contemporary and emerging strategies for eliminating human African trypanosomiasis due to Trypanosoma brucei gambiense: Review. Trop Medi Int Health. 2015; 20(6):707–18.CrossRef Steinmann P, Stone CM, Sutherland CS, Tanner M, Tediosi F. Contemporary and emerging strategies for eliminating human African trypanosomiasis due to Trypanosoma brucei gambiense: Review. Trop Medi Int Health. 2015; 20(6):707–18.CrossRef
68.
Zurück zum Zitat Lea RA. World Development Report 1993: ‘Investing in Health’. Forum Dev Stud. 1993; 20(1):114–7.CrossRef Lea RA. World Development Report 1993: ‘Investing in Health’. Forum Dev Stud. 1993; 20(1):114–7.CrossRef
69.
Zurück zum Zitat Murray C. Quantifying the burden of disease : the technical basis for disability-adjusted life years. Bull World Health Organ. 1994; 72(3):429–45.PubMedPubMedCentral Murray C. Quantifying the burden of disease : the technical basis for disability-adjusted life years. Bull World Health Organ. 1994; 72(3):429–45.PubMedPubMedCentral
70.
Zurück zum Zitat Hutubessy R, Chisholm D, Edejer TT-T. Generalized cost-effectiveness analysis for national-level priority-setting in the health sector. Cost Effect Resour Allocation. 2003; 1(1):8.CrossRef Hutubessy R, Chisholm D, Edejer TT-T. Generalized cost-effectiveness analysis for national-level priority-setting in the health sector. Cost Effect Resour Allocation. 2003; 1(1):8.CrossRef
71.
Zurück zum Zitat Leech AA, Kim DD, Cohen JT, Neumann PJ. Use and misuse of cost-effectiveness analysis thresholds in low-and middle-income countries: trends in cost-per-daly studies. Value Health. 2018; 21(7):759–61.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Leech AA, Kim DD, Cohen JT, Neumann PJ. Use and misuse of cost-effectiveness analysis thresholds in low-and middle-income countries: trends in cost-per-daly studies. Value Health. 2018; 21(7):759–61.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
72.
Zurück zum Zitat Woods B, Revill P, Sculpher M, Claxton K. Country-level cost-effectiveness thresholds: Initial estimates and the need for further research. Value Health. 2016; 19(8):929–35.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Woods B, Revill P, Sculpher M, Claxton K. Country-level cost-effectiveness thresholds: Initial estimates and the need for further research. Value Health. 2016; 19(8):929–35.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
73.
Zurück zum Zitat Ochalek J, Lomas J, Claxton K. Estimating health opportunity costs in low-income and middle-income countries: a novel approach and evidence from cross-country data. BMJ Glob health. 2018; 3(6):e000964.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Ochalek J, Lomas J, Claxton K. Estimating health opportunity costs in low-income and middle-income countries: a novel approach and evidence from cross-country data. BMJ Glob health. 2018; 3(6):e000964.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
74.
Zurück zum Zitat Bertram MY, Lauer JA, Joncheere KD, Edejer T, Hutubessy R, Kieny P, Hill SR, Bertram MY. Cost – effectiveness thresholds: pros and cons Use and misuse of thresholds. Bull World Health Organ. 2016; 94(July):925–30.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Bertram MY, Lauer JA, Joncheere KD, Edejer T, Hutubessy R, Kieny P, Hill SR, Bertram MY. Cost – effectiveness thresholds: pros and cons Use and misuse of thresholds. Bull World Health Organ. 2016; 94(July):925–30.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
75.
Zurück zum Zitat Marseille E, Larson B, Kazi DS, Kahn JG, Rosen S. Thresholds for the cost–effectiveness of interventions: Alternative approaches. Bull World Health Organ. 2015; 93(2):118–24.PubMedCrossRef Marseille E, Larson B, Kazi DS, Kahn JG, Rosen S. Thresholds for the cost–effectiveness of interventions: Alternative approaches. Bull World Health Organ. 2015; 93(2):118–24.PubMedCrossRef
76.
Zurück zum Zitat Wall RJ, Rico E, Lukac I, Zuccotto F, Elg S, Gilbert IH, Freund Y, Alley MRK, Field MC, Wyllie S, Horn D. Clinical and veterinary trypanocidal benzoxaboroles target CPSF3. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA. 2018; 115(38):9616–21.PubMedCrossRef Wall RJ, Rico E, Lukac I, Zuccotto F, Elg S, Gilbert IH, Freund Y, Alley MRK, Field MC, Wyllie S, Horn D. Clinical and veterinary trypanocidal benzoxaboroles target CPSF3. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA. 2018; 115(38):9616–21.PubMedCrossRef
78.
Zurück zum Zitat Louis F, Kohagne LT, Ebo’O VE, Simarro P. Organizing an active screening campaign for human African trypanosomiasis due to Trypanosoma brucei gambiense. Méd Trop revue du Corps de santé colonial. 2008; 68(1):11–16. Louis F, Kohagne LT, Ebo’O VE, Simarro P. Organizing an active screening campaign for human African trypanosomiasis due to Trypanosoma brucei gambiense. Méd Trop revue du Corps de santé colonial. 2008; 68(1):11–16.
79.
Zurück zum Zitat Welburn S, Maudlin I, Simarro P. Controlling sleeping sickness–a review. Parasitology. 2009; 136(14):1943–9.PubMedCrossRef Welburn S, Maudlin I, Simarro P. Controlling sleeping sickness–a review. Parasitology. 2009; 136(14):1943–9.PubMedCrossRef
80.
Zurück zum Zitat Fenwick E, Claxton K, Sculpher M. Representing uncertainty: The role of cost-effectiveness acceptability curves. Health Econ. 2001; 10(8):779–87.PubMedCrossRef Fenwick E, Claxton K, Sculpher M. Representing uncertainty: The role of cost-effectiveness acceptability curves. Health Econ. 2001; 10(8):779–87.PubMedCrossRef
81.
Zurück zum Zitat Barton GR, Briggs AH, Fenwick EAL. Optimal cost-effectiveness decisions: The role of the cost-effectiveness acceptability curve (CEAC), the cost-effectiveness acceptability frontier (CEAF), and the expected value of perfection information (EVPI). Value Health. 2008; 11(5):886–97.PubMedCrossRef Barton GR, Briggs AH, Fenwick EAL. Optimal cost-effectiveness decisions: The role of the cost-effectiveness acceptability curve (CEAC), the cost-effectiveness acceptability frontier (CEAF), and the expected value of perfection information (EVPI). Value Health. 2008; 11(5):886–97.PubMedCrossRef
82.
Zurück zum Zitat Hollingsworth TD, Adams ER, Anderson RM, Atkins K, Bartsch S, Basáñez M-g, Behrend M, Blok DJ, Chapman LAC, Coffeng L, Courtenay O, Crump RE, Vlas SJD, Dobson A, Dyson L, Farkas H, Galvani AP, Gambhir M, Gurarie D, Irvine MA, Jervis S, Keeling MJ, Kelly-hope L, King C, Lee BY, Rutte EAL, Lietman TM, Ndeffo-mbah M, Medley GF, Michael E, Pandey A, Peterson JK, Pinsent A, Porco TC, Richardus JH, Reimer L, Rock KS, Singh BK, Stolk W, Swaminathan S, Torr SJ, Townsend J, Truscott J, Walker M, Zoueva A, Consortium NTDM. Quantitative analyses and modelling to support achievement of the 2020 goals for nine neglected tropical diseases. Parasites Vectors. 2015; 8(1):630.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Hollingsworth TD, Adams ER, Anderson RM, Atkins K, Bartsch S, Basáñez M-g, Behrend M, Blok DJ, Chapman LAC, Coffeng L, Courtenay O, Crump RE, Vlas SJD, Dobson A, Dyson L, Farkas H, Galvani AP, Gambhir M, Gurarie D, Irvine MA, Jervis S, Keeling MJ, Kelly-hope L, King C, Lee BY, Rutte EAL, Lietman TM, Ndeffo-mbah M, Medley GF, Michael E, Pandey A, Peterson JK, Pinsent A, Porco TC, Richardus JH, Reimer L, Rock KS, Singh BK, Stolk W, Swaminathan S, Torr SJ, Townsend J, Truscott J, Walker M, Zoueva A, Consortium NTDM. Quantitative analyses and modelling to support achievement of the 2020 goals for nine neglected tropical diseases. Parasites Vectors. 2015; 8(1):630.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
83.
Zurück zum Zitat Hasker E, Lutumba P, Chappuis F, Kande V, Potet J, De Weggheleire A, Kambo C, Depoortere E, Pecoul B, Boelaert M. Human african trypanosomiasis in the democratic republic of the congo: a looming emergency?. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2012; 6(12):1950.CrossRef Hasker E, Lutumba P, Chappuis F, Kande V, Potet J, De Weggheleire A, Kambo C, Depoortere E, Pecoul B, Boelaert M. Human african trypanosomiasis in the democratic republic of the congo: a looming emergency?. PLoS Negl Trop Dis. 2012; 6(12):1950.CrossRef
84.
Zurück zum Zitat Ochalek JM, Lomas J, Claxton KP. Cost per DALY averted thresholds for low- and middle-income countries: evidence from cross country data. York: Centre for Health Economics, University of York; 2015, pp. 1–50. (CHE Research Paper; 122). Ochalek JM, Lomas J, Claxton KP. Cost per DALY averted thresholds for low- and middle-income countries: evidence from cross country data. York: Centre for Health Economics, University of York; 2015, pp. 1–50. (CHE Research Paper; 122).
Metadaten
Titel
Cost-effectiveness modelling to optimise active screening strategy for gambiense human African trypanosomiasis in endemic areas of the Democratic Republic of Congo
verfasst von
Christopher N. Davis
Kat S. Rock
Marina Antillón
Erick Mwamba Miaka
Matt J. Keeling
Publikationsdatum
01.12.2021
Verlag
BioMed Central
Erschienen in
BMC Medicine / Ausgabe 1/2021
Elektronische ISSN: 1741-7015
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1186/s12916-021-01943-4

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2021

BMC Medicine 1/2021 Zur Ausgabe

Leitlinien kompakt für die Allgemeinmedizin

Mit medbee Pocketcards sicher entscheiden.

Seit 2022 gehört die medbee GmbH zum Springer Medizin Verlag

Facharzt-Training Allgemeinmedizin

Die ideale Vorbereitung zur anstehenden Prüfung mit den ersten 24 von 100 klinischen Fallbeispielen verschiedener Themenfelder

Mehr erfahren

Neu im Fachgebiet Allgemeinmedizin

Update Allgemeinmedizin

Bestellen Sie unseren Fach-Newsletter und bleiben Sie gut informiert.