Skip to main content
Erschienen in: International Journal of Health Economics and Management 3/2020

06.03.2020 | Research article

Do the uninsured demand less care? Evidence from Maryland’s hospitals

verfasst von: Amanda Cook

Erschienen in: International Journal of Health Economics and Management | Ausgabe 3/2020

Einloggen, um Zugang zu erhalten

Abstract

Uninsured individuals receive fewer healthcare services for at least three reasons: responsibility for the entire bill, higher prices, and potential provider reductions for concern of nonpayment. I isolate reductions when uninsured patients are solely financially responsible by capitalizing on Maryland’s highly regulated health care system. Prices are set by the state, are uniform across all patients, and hospitals are compensated for free care and bad debt. I use a unique feature of the data, multiple readmissions for patients who gain or lose insurance between visits, to isolate the reductions in quantity demanded when individuals are faced with paying the full price without an insurance contribution. A Blinder–Oaxaca decomposition estimates uninsured individuals receive 6% fewer services after accounting for differences in patient, illness, and hospital characteristics than when these same individuals are insured.
Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
This is a fee for service environment, but is unusual in that hospital- rate center- specific prices are set by the HSCRC. Additionally, there are limits to the total number of services a hospital can provide in a year based on their aggregate patient mix.
 
2
A patient is categorized into a listing of diagnosis or procedure. This initial categorization is the root Diagnosis Related Group (DRG). There are 314 root DRGs in Maryland. Once the root DRG has been established, secondary diagnosis and other factors (obesity, other illnesses) are then considered and the patient is assigned a severity class (1–4). For severity, the 1–4 scale runs low to high. The combination of the root DRG and the level of severity form the APRDRG (Systems 2013).
 
4
For government payers there is, at most, a 6% difference between Medicare/Medicaid and non-Medicare/Medicaid patients. This doesn’t create an incentive to provide fewer services to government payers, however, because when a hospital’s base rate is established, the fraction of government patients is considered and built into the base rate. If a hospital serves more government payers, its base rate increases the next year, if it serves fewer, it declines. As such, a hospital has no financial incentive to provide a differential service mix to different payers. Details of how the base rate is established can be found in Appendix 1.
 
5
Some individuals may chose to be uninsured if they believe their private health signal is very good, believing they will not get sick or injured. One might be concerned that individuals with good private health information may be healthier than average and more likely to be uninsured. However, in the data, I restrict my sample to inpatient admissions. Figure 3 illustrates that there is not a clear relationship between APRDRG weight (a measure of severity) and services. Furthermore, Long et al. (1998) find that individuals are unable to anticipate changes to insurance status to take advantage of periods of relatively generous insurance. This suggests that reductions to services observed in this paper are not ‘consumption smoothing’ on the part of the uninsured. While some young people improperly estimate their risks of illness, and have been termed the ‘young invincibles’ (Smith 2014), the remainder of this analysis will focus on an income constraint as being the driving motivation for remaining uninsured.
 
6
I only observe if a patient returns to the same hospital for an additional visit. I can not observe I they go to Hospital A and then Hospital B. This is a limitation of the data, and of the study.
 
7
This assumes that their job is n the formal sector and is paying payroll taxes on their behalf.
 
8
\(0.0271=-279.6/-1032.4\).
 
9
\(0.773=798.5/1032.4\).
 
10
\(0.078=-1032.4/13{,}317.9\).
 
11
\(0.06=-798.5/-13{,}317.9.\)
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Baicker, K., Taubman, S. L., Allen, H. L., Bernstein, M., Gruber, J. H., Newhouse, J. P., et al. (2013). The Oregon experiment—Effects of Medicaid on clinical outcomes. New England Journal of Medicine, 368(18), 1713–1722.PubMedCrossRef Baicker, K., Taubman, S. L., Allen, H. L., Bernstein, M., Gruber, J. H., Newhouse, J. P., et al. (2013). The Oregon experiment—Effects of Medicaid on clinical outcomes. New England Journal of Medicine, 368(18), 1713–1722.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bruen, B. K., Ku, L., Lu, X., & Shin, P. (2013). No evidence that primary care physicians offer less care to medicaid, community health center, or uninsured patients. Health Affairs, 32(9), 1624–1630.PubMedCrossRef Bruen, B. K., Ku, L., Lu, X., & Shin, P. (2013). No evidence that primary care physicians offer less care to medicaid, community health center, or uninsured patients. Health Affairs, 32(9), 1624–1630.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Buchmueller, T. C., Grumbach, K., Kronick, R., & Kahn, J. G. (2005). Book review: The effect of health insurance on medical care utilization and implications for insurance expansion: A review of the literature. Medical Care Research and Review, 62(1), 3–30.PubMedCrossRef Buchmueller, T. C., Grumbach, K., Kronick, R., & Kahn, J. G. (2005). Book review: The effect of health insurance on medical care utilization and implications for insurance expansion: A review of the literature. Medical Care Research and Review, 62(1), 3–30.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cooper, Z., Craig, S. V., Gaynor, M., & Van Reenen, J. (2019). The price ain’t right? Hospital prices and health spending on the privately insured. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 134(1), 51–107. Cooper, Z., Craig, S. V., Gaynor, M., & Van Reenen, J. (2019). The price ain’t right? Hospital prices and health spending on the privately insured. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 134(1), 51–107.
Zurück zum Zitat Currie, J., & Gruber, J. (2001). Public health insurance and medical treatment: the equalizing impact of the medicaid expansions. Journal of Public Economics, 82(1), 63–89.CrossRef Currie, J., & Gruber, J. (2001). Public health insurance and medical treatment: the equalizing impact of the medicaid expansions. Journal of Public Economics, 82(1), 63–89.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Doyle, J. J. (2005). Health insurance, treatment and outcomes: Using auto accidents as health shocks. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 87(2), 256–270.CrossRef Doyle, J. J. (2005). Health insurance, treatment and outcomes: Using auto accidents as health shocks. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 87(2), 256–270.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat HSCRC. (December 4, 2013). Report on results of uncompensated care policy and final recommendation to suspend the formula for calculating the hospital specific results. HSCRC. (December 4, 2013). Report on results of uncompensated care policy and final recommendation to suspend the formula for calculating the hospital specific results.
Zurück zum Zitat Keeler, E. B., & Rolph, J. E. (1988). The demand for episodes of treatment in the health insurance experiment. Journal of Health Economics, 7(4), 337–367.PubMedCrossRef Keeler, E. B., & Rolph, J. E. (1988). The demand for episodes of treatment in the health insurance experiment. Journal of Health Economics, 7(4), 337–367.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lefgren, L., & McIntyre, F. (2009). Explaining the puzzle of crossstate differences in bankruptcy rates. The Journal of Law & Economics, 52(2), 367–393.CrossRef Lefgren, L., & McIntyre, F. (2009). Explaining the puzzle of crossstate differences in bankruptcy rates. The Journal of Law & Economics, 52(2), 367–393.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Long, S. H., Marquis, M. S., & Rodgers, J. (1998). Do people shift their use of health services over time to take advantage of insurance? Journal of Health Economics, 17(1), 105–115.PubMedCrossRef Long, S. H., Marquis, M. S., & Rodgers, J. (1998). Do people shift their use of health services over time to take advantage of insurance? Journal of Health Economics, 17(1), 105–115.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mahoney, N. (2015). Bankruptcy as implicit health insurance. American Economic Review, 105(2), 710–46.PubMedCrossRef Mahoney, N. (2015). Bankruptcy as implicit health insurance. American Economic Review, 105(2), 710–46.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Manning, W. G., Newhouse, J. P., Duan, N., Keeler, E. B., & Leibowitz, A. (1987). Health insurance and the demand for medical care: Evidence from a randomized experiment. The American Economic Review, 77, 251–277.PubMed Manning, W. G., Newhouse, J. P., Duan, N., Keeler, E. B., & Leibowitz, A. (1987). Health insurance and the demand for medical care: Evidence from a randomized experiment. The American Economic Review, 77, 251–277.PubMed
Zurück zum Zitat Marquis, M. S., & Long, S. H. (1994–1995). The uninsured access gap: Narrowing the estimates. Inquiry, 31(4), 405–414. Marquis, M. S., & Long, S. H. (1994–1995). The uninsured access gap: Narrowing the estimates. Inquiry, 31(4), 405–414.
Zurück zum Zitat Murray, R. (2009). Setting hospital rates to control costs and boost quality: The maryland experience. Health Affairs, 28(5), 1395–1405.PubMedCrossRef Murray, R. (2009). Setting hospital rates to control costs and boost quality: The maryland experience. Health Affairs, 28(5), 1395–1405.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Reinhardt, U. E. (2011). The many different prices paid to providers and the flawed theory of cost shifting: Is it time for a more rational all-payer system? Health Affairs, 30(11), 2125–2133.PubMedCrossRef Reinhardt, U. E. (2011). The many different prices paid to providers and the flawed theory of cost shifting: Is it time for a more rational all-payer system? Health Affairs, 30(11), 2125–2133.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Weissman, J. S., & Epstein, A. M. (1993). The insurance gap: Does it make a difference? Annual Review of Public Health, 14(1), 243–270.PubMedCrossRef Weissman, J. S., & Epstein, A. M. (1993). The insurance gap: Does it make a difference? Annual Review of Public Health, 14(1), 243–270.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat White, C., Bond, A. M., Reschovsky, J. D., & LTHPOLICY, P. C. (2013). High and varying prices for privately insured patients underscore hospital market power. Center for Studying Health System Change Research Brief No. White, C., Bond, A. M., Reschovsky, J. D., & LTHPOLICY, P. C. (2013). High and varying prices for privately insured patients underscore hospital market power. Center for Studying Health System Change Research Brief No.
Zurück zum Zitat White, F. A., French, D., Zwemer, F. L., & Fairbanks, R. J. (2007). Care without coverage: Is there a relationship between insurance and ed care? The Journal of Emergency Medicine, 32(2), 159–165.PubMedCrossRef White, F. A., French, D., Zwemer, F. L., & Fairbanks, R. J. (2007). Care without coverage: Is there a relationship between insurance and ed care? The Journal of Emergency Medicine, 32(2), 159–165.PubMedCrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Do the uninsured demand less care? Evidence from Maryland’s hospitals
verfasst von
Amanda Cook
Publikationsdatum
06.03.2020
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
International Journal of Health Economics and Management / Ausgabe 3/2020
Print ISSN: 2199-9023
Elektronische ISSN: 2199-9031
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10754-020-09280-4

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3/2020

International Journal of Health Economics and Management 3/2020 Zur Ausgabe