What drives health care expenditure?—Baumol's model of ‘unbalanced growth’ revisited

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2007.05.006Get rights and content

Abstract

The share of health care expenditure in GDP rises rapidly in virtually all OECD countries, causing increasing concern among politicians and the general public. Yet, economists have to date failed to reach an agreement on what the main determinants of this development are. This paper revisits Baumol's [Baumol, W.J., 1967. Macroeconomics of unbalanced growth: the anatomy of urban crisis. American Economic Review 57 (3), 415–426] model of ‘unbalanced growth’, showing that the latter offers a ready explanation for the observed inexorable rise in health care expenditure. The main implication of Baumol's model in this context is that health care expenditure is driven by wage increases in excess of productivity growth. This hypothesis is tested empirically using data from a panel of 19 OECD countries. Our tests yield robust evidence in favor of Baumol's theory.

Introduction

The share of current health care expenditure (HCE) in the gross domestic product (GDP) rises rapidly in virtually all developed nations. Fig. 1 illustrates this for a couple of countries for which data are available back to 1960. According to the OECD's health database 2005, only two countries (Denmark and Ireland) record similar shares as 20 years ago. In the U.S. on the other hand, the share has risen from 4.8% in 1960 to 14.7% in 2003. This is the highest value of all OECD nations. Switzerland ranks second in this statistic with a share 11.3% in 2003 (up from 4.8% in 1960). An opinion poll carried out in this country in early 2006 revealed rising ‘health care costs’ to be the most worrisome topic for Swiss households (cf. NZZ, 2006).

In view of this large public concern, it is unfortunate how little we know about the factors that drive the rapid rise in HCE. Back in 1994, Hoffmeyer and McCarthy (1994, p. 67) wrote that “there is just one, very clear, very well-established statistical fact relating to health care expenditure: its correlation with GDP. No other robust and stable correlations have yet been found.” This statement is confirmed by Roberts (1999) who dates the starting point of cross-country research into the determinants of HCE back to Newhouse (1977) and then writes: “During this time [the past 20 years] there has been little progress beyond the finding that variations in per capita national income are closely correlated with variations in per capita health spending” (Roberts, 1999, p. 459).

In the literature this judgment is based on we can distinguish two stages. Between the mid-1970s and the mid-1990s, scholars such as Kleiman (1974), Newhouse, 1977, Newhouse, 1987, Cullis and West (1979), Leu (1986), Parkin et al. (1987), Culyer (1990), Milne and Molana (1991), Getzen and Poullier (1991), Gerdtham and Jönsson, 1991a, Gerdtham and Jönsson, 1991b, Gerdtham et al. (1992), and Hitiris and Posnett (1992) provided evidence for a positive correlation between HCE and GDP (mostly) in OECD data. This correlation was found to be robust to varying years covered, estimators and use of conversion factors (such as deflators, exchange rates, or health care purchasing power parities). Other intuitively plausible explanatory variables were normally not found to be statistically significant.1 An important issue in this first stage of research was the question whether health care is a ‘luxury good’, i.e. whether a larger than proportionate increase in income is spent on health care (cf. Getzen, 2000).

In the more recent stage of research – which started with Murthy and Ukpolo (1994) and Hansen and King (1996) – the time series properties of the variables in question have received more attention than before.2 Unit root and cointegration tests were performed for HCE and GDP. The results of these tests have been somewhat inconclusive and not very robust to the choice of the testing methodology. Hansen and King (1996), for instance, found no cointegration between HCE and GDP for all OECD countries except Iceland applying the Engle–Granger (EG) two-step method and testing the residuals from the cointegrating regression with the Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) test. Blomqvist and Carter (1997) reversed the result using the Phillips–Perron (PP) test for the second step. There is a related controversy on whether the variables are non-stationary in the first place. McCoskey and Selden (1998) reject the null hypothesis of unit roots for HCE and GDP while Roberts (1999) finds both variables to be non-stationary. Based on country-by-country as well as panel cointegration tests, Gerdtham and Löthgren (2000) confirm that both health expenditure and GDP have a unit root and that they are cointegrated. Yet, as the latest twist in this debate come the contributions by Jewell et al. (2003) and Carrion-i-Silvestre (2005) who, for the first time in this body of literature, consider the possibility of structural breaks in the time series. Using data from 20 OECD countries, they find both HCE and GDP to be stationary around up to five structural breaks.

Reviewing the literature, we cannot help but admit that despite intense research efforts, we do not really know the degree of integration of health expenditure variables. Unfortunately, given that the available time series are rather short, which lowers the power of the tests, and that the number of competing tests is huge (and growing), some uncertainty is likely to remain with respect to the properties of the time series analyzed in this field of research.

A fresh approach might be attractive not only for methodological, but also for theoretical reasons. Over the past 30 years, research into the determinants of health care expenditure has concentrated on – and to some degree even confined itself to – evaluating the connection between national health expenditure and GDP. As already mentioned, attempts to detect other explanatory variables – or explanatory variables proper, since a correlation between health care expenditure and GDP does not explain much in terms of causal relations, unless one adopts a crude version of Keynesianism – have been sporadic and largely unsuccessful.3 Not even such obvious candidates as population shares above certain age thresholds (e.g., 65 years or 75 years) have been found to contribute to the explanation of health care expenditure – except in a few studies, e.g., Hitiris and Posnett (1992), Di Matteo and Di Matteo (1998), and Okunade et al. (2004). Zweifel et al. (1999) show that ‘proximity to death’ rather than ageing drives health care expenditure. Evidently, this variable is contemporaneously unknown and hence inoperative for models intending to forecast HCE.4

“Economists have not developed a formal theory to explain or to predict the per capita medical care expenditure of a nation”, concludes Wilson (1999, p. 160). He continues: “In the absence of a theory, empirical work in this field has necessarily been based on ad-hoc reasoning and data availability” (Wilson (1999, p. 160)).

Of course, Wilson's claim could be disputed on the grounds that Grossman (1972) has introduced a micro-founded model of the demand for health. But the Grossman model is concerned with the individual's demand for health, while Wilson bemoans the absence of a theory that would explain aggregate medical care expenditure. To reduce the Grossman model to a form that can be tested empirically with aggregate data has turned out to be cumbersome since important explanatory variables are unobservable (cf. Wagstaff, 1986, Erbsland et al., 1998, Nocera and Zweifel, 1998). After all, both Roberts (1999) and Gerdtham and Jönsson (2000) call for strengthening the theoretical basis for the macroeconomic analysis of health expenditure. According to Roberts (1999, p. 470), this must be the “primary aim for future work”.

We here intend to meet this demand, revisiting Baumol's (1967) theory of ‘unbalanced growth’. Baumol develops a simple neoclassical growth model that allows for explicit predictions of the future course of health expenditure. These predictions can be tested empirically. As far as we see, Baumol's model has so far largely escaped the attention of health economists.5 The next section introduces the model, and Section 3 discusses one of its more controversial implications – namely that labor productivity growth in the health sector must be expected to remain low – with special attention to measurement issues. Section 4 moves on to testing the main implications auf Baumol's model empirically. Section 5 presents the results of robustness checks; Section 6 draws some conclusions for health policy, and Section 7 concludes.

Section snippets

Baumol's model of ‘unbalanced growth’

It is a hallmark of the work of William J. Baumol that it is concerned with recasting neoclassical models in a more ‘realistic’ form (cf. Eliasson and Henrekson, 2004). Baumol's (1967) American Economic Review paper ‘Macroeconomics of unbalanced growth: the anatomy of urban crisis’ is no exception in this respect. In this paper, Baumol divides the economy into two parts: a ‘progressive’ and a ‘non-progressive’ sector. He then makes several assumptions, only one of which he claims to be really

Prices and productivity growth in the health sector: measurement issues

Baumol counts the health sector among the ‘non-progressive’ sectors in which there is no ‘regular’ productivity growth. This might be debatable. Already the Boskin Commission (Boskin et al., 1996) suspected the medical care price index in the U.S. to be substantially upward-biased due to a failure to account for quality improvements in treatments, for example the reduction of pain thanks to minimum invasive surgery. In line with earlier studies (e.g., Triplett, 1999, Berndt et al., 2000),

Testing Baumol's model of ‘unbalanced growth’ empirically

How relevant is Baumol's model of ‘unbalanced growth’? One way of assessing its relevance is to check whether the model's assumptions and predictions have empirical grounding. This is done by Hartwig (2005) using Swiss data. He confirms that labor productivity growth is much higher in manufacturing than in any other industry.7 Nominal wages in manufacturing and in the tertiary sector seem to be

Robustness analysis

We now turn to the question of how robust our results are to variations in the modeling framework. We will perform three types of robustness tests. First, we ask whether the inclusion of another explanatory variable alters the results. This additional explanatory variable will, of course, be per-capita GDP growth, as GDP has emerged as the only uncontroversial explanatory variable for per-capita HCE from the literature. Other variables could, of course, be tested also, but it is of prime

A short note on the implications of our findings for health policy

Our study adds empirical support to Baumol's model of ‘unbalanced growth’. If this model has identified a major cause of the continuous rise in health expenditure correctly, what are the consequences for health policy? To be more specific, what can health policy do to prevent HCE from rising further?

Unfortunately, the answer must be: not much. Baumol's analysis reveals a fundamental supply-side factor to be the main driver behind health expenditure, namely the fact that in the health sector

Conclusion

In their contribution for the Handbook of Health Economics, Gerdtham and Jönsson (2000, p. 48) identify three important issues for future research into the determinants of health care expenditure (HCE). First, they call for “more theory of the macroeconomics of health expenditure”. Second, they encourage researchers to move away from focusing on GDP as the only (uncontroversial) explanatory variable for HCE and to test ‘new’ variables. Finally, Gerdtham and Jönsson propose to study growth rates

Acknowledgements

I wish to thank Yngve Abrahamsen, Erdal Atukeren, Christian Conrad, Axel Dreher, Martin Gassebner, Christian Müller, Sarah Rupprecht, Sheila D. Smith, Jan-Egbert Sturm, Philippe Ulmann, and two anonymous referees of this journal for their valuable comments. The usual disclaimer applies.

References (71)

  • T. Hitiris et al.

    The determinants and effects of health expenditure in developed countries

    Journal of Health Economics

    (1992)
  • K.S. Im et al.

    Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels

    Journal of Econometrics

    (2003)
  • T. Jewell et al.

    Stationarity of health expenditures and GDP: evidence from panel unit root tests with heterogeneous structural breaks

    Journal of Health Economics

    (2003)
  • A. Kander

    Baumol's disease and dematerialization of the economy

    Ecological Economics

    (2005)
  • A. Levin et al.

    Unit root tests in panel data: asymptotic and finite-sample properties

    Journal of Econometrics

    (2002)
  • S.K. McCoskey et al.

    Health care expenditures and GDP: panel data unit root test results

    Journal of Health Economics

    (1998)
  • J.P. Newhouse

    Cross-national differences in health spending: what do they mean?

    Journal of Health Economics

    (1987)
  • D. Parkin et al.

    Aggregate health care expenditures and national income: is health care a luxury good?

    Journal of Health Economics

    (1987)
  • J.R. Seale

    A general theory of national expenditure on medical care

    Lancet

    (1959)
  • M. Seshamani et al.

    A longitudinal study of age and time to death on hospital costs

    Journal of Health Economics

    (2004)
  • B. Abel-Smith

    Cost Containment in Health Care

    (1984)
  • Ahmad, N., Lequiller, F., Marianna, P., Pilat, D., Schreyer, P., Wölfl, A., 2003. Comparing labour productivity growth...
  • Ahnert, H., Kenny, G., 2004. Quality adjustment of European price statistics and the role for hedonics. European...
  • P.P. Barros

    The black box of health care expenditure growth determinants

    Health Economics

    (1998)
  • W.J. Baumol

    Macroeconomics of unbalanced growth: the anatomy of urban crisis

    American Economic Review

    (1967)
  • W.J. Baumol

    Health care, education and the cost disease: a looming crisis for public choice

    Public Choice

    (1993)
  • E.R. Berndt et al.

    Medical care prices and output

  • M.J. Boskin et al.
  • J. Breitung

    The local power of some unit root tests for panel data

  • B. Catron et al.

    Hospital price inflation: what does the new PPI tell us?

    Monthly Labor Review

    (1996)
  • J.G. Cullis et al.

    The Economics of Health: An Introduction

    (1979)
  • A.J. Culyer

    Cost containment in Europe

    Health Care Systems in Transition

    (1990)
  • G. Eliasson et al.

    William J. Baumol: an entrepreneurial economist on the economics of entrepreneurship

    Small Business Economics

    (2004)
  • M. Erbsland et al.

    The impact of the environment on the demands for health and health care: an empirical analysis for Germany

  • Cited by (157)

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text