Skip to main content
Erschienen in: The European Journal of Health Economics 2/2021

Open Access 23.12.2020 | Original Paper

Voluntary private health insurance, health-related behaviours and health outcomes: evidence from Russia

verfasst von: Andrey Aistov, Ekaterina Aleksandrova, Christopher J. Gerry

Erschienen in: The European Journal of Health Economics | Ausgabe 2/2021

Abstract

This paper contributes to the discussion around ex-post (increased utilisation of health care) and ex-ante (changes in health behaviours) moral hazard in supplemental private health insurance. Applying a range of methodologies to data from the Russian Longitudinal Monitoring Survey—Higher School of Economics we exploit a selection mechanism in the data to compare the impact of workplace provided and individually purchased supplemental health insurance on the utilisation of health care, on a range of health behaviours and on self-assessed health. We find compelling policy-relevant evidence of ex-post moral hazard that confirms a theoretical prediction and empirical regularity found in other settings. In contrast to other empirical findings though, our data reveals evidence of ex-ante moral hazard demonstrated by clear behavioural differences between those with self-funded supplemental health insurance and those for whom the workplace finances the additional insurance. We find no evidence that either form of insurance is related to improved self-assessed health.
Hinweise

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Introduction

A wealth of empirical evidence confirms the theoretical prediction that health insurance lowers the price of utilising health care at the point of access and, therefore, gives rise to increased health care consumption. In the absence of being able to perfectly observe individuals’ motives, behaviours or actions, the empirical literature has to overcome the challenge that health insurance arrangements also give rise to adverse selection and to various realisations of moral hazard. The RAND [1] and Oregon [2] Health Insurance Experiments, in the United States, have prompted numerous empirical studies which have been able to robustly identify the relationship between health insurance and health care utilisation by drawing on evidence from experimental settings. Nevertheless, these experiments have not resulted in a consensus concerning the, less theoretically clear, link between health insurance, health outcomes and other forms of health behaviour. A related and swiftly evolving body of literature has sought further empirical settings and methodologies to explore the relationships between health insurance, health behaviours and health outcomes in countries other than the United States and with different health care systems.
This paper adds to that literature, seeking to better understand the complex relationships between health insurance and health-related outcomes by examining longitudinal data from the Russian Federation. In the spirit of many European health care systems, Russian health care is financed through a mandatory health insurance (MHI) system, which—in principle—offers comprehensive health care to Russian citizens, free at the point of delivery. In reality, the system is seriously under-financed, the care—which is of variable quality—is far from comprehensive, and access to it is characterised by regional, demographic and socio-economic inequalities related to the individuals’ capacity to make out-of-pocket payments. Against this background, for the minority who could afford it, a private health insurance system emerged in the 1990s to supplement the mandatory system. More recently, as supplemental private insurance has grown in popularity and increasingly been offered through the workplace, policy discussions have focused on whether and to what extent supplemental health insurance can be an active tool for addressing the short-comings and financial constraints inherent to the current system.
We draw on longitudinal data from the Russian Longitudinal Monitoring Survey—Higher School of Economics (RLMS-HSE), which allows us to attenuate the problem of adverse selection by distinguishing between individuals who self-select supplemental health insurance and those that have it provided for them through their place of employment. As we explain later on, it is improbable in Russia, and empirically unsupported, that respondents would choose their employment based on the prospect of their employer providing a supplemental insurance cover. Therefore, using this framework of insurance ‘types’, we can explore the impact that supplemental health insurance has on health care access, good and bad health behaviours and self-assessed health status. We provide, to our knowledge, the first such study focusing on Russia, we distinguish between ex-post and ex-ante moral hazard and explore how these vary according to gender, age, education, and region, using a range of econometric techniques, including a novel ‘Blow Up and Cluster’ (BUC) method [3] which we do not believe has been used in this context previously. Our results are relevant for the general literature on health insurance and its impact on behaviours and actions but are particularly important for countries, such as Russia, who are reforming and modernising the structure and finance of their health care systems and debating the appropriate mix of social and private insurance.
Consistent with the early strands of related literature, we find compelling evidence of ex-post moral hazard but, in contrast to much of the empirical literature, we also find evidence of ex-ante moral hazard demonstrated by significant behavioural differences between those with self-funded and enterprise provided supplemental health insurance. We find limited evidence that either form of insurance is related to improved self-assessed health. We interpret these results as suggestive of the need for health insurance plans to incorporate more explicit incentives to ‘nudge’ behaviour in ways that will reduce the future flow of health care costs associated with risky health activities such as smoking, drinking and the absence of exercise. In addition, we note that further work needs to be undertaken to understand the efficiency-equity trade-offs implied by policies, such as mandatory health insurance, which increase access to health care while also stimulating its overuse.
We proceed as follows. Section two reviews the global literature on health insurance, health care and health related behaviour, making clear how important the institutional settings are for any empirical analysis. In section three, we therefore spell out the specificities of the Russian health care system and its financing. The subsequent section describes our data and details our empirical strategy, including as it relates to the crucial aspect of selection. Section five presents our empirical results which are then explored in greater detail in the final section, incorporating considerations for health policy as well as directions for future research.

Health insurance, health care and health-related behaviour

The most straightforward theoretical implication of health insurance is that, other things being equal, it will result in increased consumption of health care due to what Arrow [4] famously identified as moral hazard. There are essentially two sources of moral hazard which can give rise to this phenomenon: ex-ante (relating to the individual propensity to invest in health) and ex-post (relating to the price sensitivity of demand for health care). The former, due to Ehrlich and Becker [5] captures the idea that health insurance reduces the incentives for individuals to invest in their health and, therefore, will be associated with unhealthy behaviours, including increased smoking and drinking, along with decreased exercise and less appropriate diets [6]. In contrast, ex-post moral hazard takes the individual’s health as given and posits that, at any given level of health, individuals with insurance will consume more health care, because the price of health care is lower [7].
While moral hazard provides for interesting theoretical implications, the theory does not provide us with predictions of the impact of health insurance on either health outcomes or on social welfare. First, the impact on health outcomes is unclear, because any (presumed) benefits of increased health care utilisation may be offset by ex-ante reductions in health investments. Second, diminishing marginal returns to health care imply that the impact of additional consumption depends on the initial individual stock of health capital [8]. Put differently, the impact on social welfare ultimately depends on the following combination of factors: the balance of increased (decreased) use of efficacious (inefficacious) medical services [9]; the relationship between health insurance and health behaviours; and the extent to which increased use of medical services is linked with positive changes in health behaviour.
To further complicate matters, identifying the existence of moral hazard presents a methodological challenge, since in most empirical settings, there are fundamental selection differences between those with and without insurance [10, 11]. The ‘high risks’ (i.e., least healthy) self-select into insurance, so that both adverse selection and moral hazard are consistent with greater ex-post utilisation of health care [12]. This renders it challenging to disentangle moral hazard from selection effects but is of crucial importance from a policy perspective, since policies to address adverse selection (e.g., mandatory insurance) may exacerbate moral hazard [13].
The classical theoretical studies referred to above paved the way for a rich seam of empirical health economics research, much of which has been linked to the famous health insurance ‘experiments’ implemented in the United States. Both the RAND Health Insurance Experiment, from the 1970s [1, 14] and the Oregon Health Insurance Experiment, from the 2000s [2] found compelling evidence of ex-post moral hazard: that is, spending on health care is lower when consumer cost-sharing and out-of-pocket spending requirements are higher. “Moral hazard, in other words, irrefutably exists” [15].
These findings have found succour outside of experimental settings, where additional care to avoid conflating moral hazard and adverse selection is called for. Inevitably, given the role of private and public insurance and the two experiments referred to above, much of this literature has focused on the United States. Expansions of Medicaid and Medicare, supplemental insurance (e.g., Medigap), and the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (ACA) reforms have all been strongly associated with increased utilisation of medical care with and without strong evidence of adverse selection [1623].
European countries have had few policy ‘experiments’ comparable to those in the US and so the literature for European countries is sparser. France provides one interesting exception [24], with a natural co-payment experiment from the 1990s, confirming demand for some physician services is responsive to adjustments in the co-payment rate. The French system, not unlike the Russian system, offers patients more freedom to see a specialist directly, but, while insurance is shown to strongly influence overall use of physician services, there is no evidence of it proving decisive in the decision between physician and specialist [25]. Though not benefitting from the same natural exogeneity as in the French case, other institutional settings across Europe provide further evidence of ex-post moral hazard in Ireland [26], Denmark [27], Spain [28], Switzerland [29] and Germany [30].
Discussions of moral hazard have predominantly adopted the ex-post definition but, as the link between unhealthy behaviours, population health and the growth of health care expenditure becomes better understood, explorations of ex-ante moral hazard have proliferated, drawing attention to a related set of empirical challenges. There are myriad different—good and bad—health behaviours, including those associated with exercise, diet and the consumption of drugs and alcohol, all of which are influenced by multiple environmental, social and economic factors. Even where we observe that smoking or alcohol use do not increase after the uptake of insurance, it is not clear whether this is because the Grossman type theoretical incentives are inoperative (i.e., no pure ex-ante moral hazard) or whether the greater use of medical services has a counter-balancing effect on health behaviours [31, 32]. What evidence there is, is mixed.
From the RAND experiment [33], the authors find no empirical link between smoking or body weight and insurance coverage. Similarly, Finkelstein et al. [2] report no evidence of ex-ante moral hazard in the Oregon Medicaid experiment. In non-experimental settings, Dave and Kaestner [31] argue that Medicare is associated with lower levels of physical activity and increased smoking and drinking, while Courtemanche and Zapata [34] find that the Massachusetts reforms were associated with lower body mass index but did not affect smoking or physical activity. Following the recent ACA expansion of dependent insurance for young adults in the United States, Barbaresco et al. [35] find weak evidence of ex-ante moral hazard and only in the case of alcohol consumption patterns, while Courtemanche et al. [36], despite evidence of ex-post moral hazard, find limited impacts on either behaviours or outcomes.
More recently, Lee [37], examining the same reforms, finds that health insurance coverage has no effect on the health behaviours or preventative care of young Americans. Others argue [38] that the theoretical relationship between insurance and risky behaviours is ambiguous and find no empirical evidence that ACA Medicaid expansion resulted in increased risky health behaviours. In contrast, Stanciole [39], modelling the insurance and behaviour choices as sequential and interdependent, finds that health insurance has significant incentive effects on lifestyle choices, increasing the tendency towards heavy smoking, sedentarism and obesity and decreasing the tendency towards binge drinking. Kelly and Markowitz [40] conclude that health insurance can impact risky health behaviours, as well as outcomes and access, but that the effects are strongly influenced by the institutional context. Outside of the US, Courbage and Coulon [41] explore how private health insurance in the UK affects the demand for (insured) preventive care and (uninsured) individual behaviours. They find that health insurance increases the propensity for exercise and for breast screening while reducing the likelihood of smoking.
A crucial strand of the argument for extending coverage is that health insurance improves health [34] and yet, as with ex-ante moral hazard, the evidence linking health and health insurance is not conclusive. In the RAND experiment the positive impact of insurance on health is limited to certain sub-groups, such as the poor [14, 33]. Finkelstein et al. [2] find that self-reported physical and mental well-being both improve in the Oregon experiment, while expansions to Medicaid have been shown to improve infant health [20] and reduce child hospitalisations [21]. Evidence of the impact on health of Medicare is also mixed. Card et al. [18] find improved self-rated health for certain sub-groups, while Finkelstein and McKnight [42] find no evidence of improved mortality rates among the insured. Meanwhile, the Massachusetts reforms have been linked with improved self-assessed health, along with decreased mortality rates [38, 43], while the recent ACA dependent provision reforms have also been linked with improved self-reported health [36, 44]. A more recent strand of international literature, covering China, Japan and Canada [4548] seeks to explore the possible causes of any potential positive health effect by identifying plausible mechanisms such as the link between increased interaction with health services and improved health behaviours.
In sum, while the fact of the relationship (if not the size) between insurance and ex-post moral hazard is both theoretically and empirically well-established, the link between insurance and preventative care use, risky health behaviours and health outcomes is both theoretically and empirically ambiguous. Health insurance has price and income effects as well as possible ex-ante moral hazard effects and the net outcomes are context and sub-group specific. More specifically, the effects of extending insurance coverage depend on the specific institutional features of the health-care system as well as the social, economic and demographic specificities which drive behaviour. We, therefore, turn next to the specifics of the Russian case.

The Russian institutional context

The Russian health system is based on a mandatory health insurance (MHI) premium paid by employers. In principle, this finances a national health system which is free at the point of access. In reality, the health system is underfunded and inefficient and many Russians fail to access the health care they require. Indeed, drugs are not covered by Russian health insurance schemes, though there are complementary drug provision and subsidy schemes targeting sections of the population [49]. In practice, therefore, there are three (non-mutually exclusive) access routes to medical care in Russia: employer-financed MHI; out-of-pocket payments; or voluntary health insurance (VHI).1 As in the French system, discussed above, Russians have some discretion over whether to see a general practitioner or to go directly to a hospital-based specialist. The former is more common under the MHI system but, even then, there is regional variation and substantial flexibility.
A small minority of Russians have access to supplementary VHI schemes either through their employer (who gains tax benefits in return) or through purchasing them directly. The mandatory health insurance provides for a minimum defined set of free health care services, while VHI contracts expand the range of services available. These VHI schemes provide enhanced access to a higher quality range of health services which can be used in supplement to or instead of MHI and/or out-of-pocket payments. These two variants of health insurance exist simultaneously and often duplicate each other. Over time, it is hoped that the VHI schemes will replace what had become ubiquitous practices of, formal or less formal, out-of-pocket payments paving the way to more rapid or higher quality health care provision. For most Russians though, the cost of VHI is prohibitive and the self-financing of VHI contracts remains rare. Indeed, according to the Russian Bureau of Statistics [50], only 5.4% of all medical appointments are VHI-related and, in Moscow and St. Petersburg, corporate VHI contracts account for 95% of the VHI market. Nevertheless, the health insurance market is growing and the number of VHI contracts has increased from around 6.6 million in 2000 to almost 11.4 million in 2016, corresponding to approximately 4.5–8% of the Russian population [51]. More recent analysis shows that the turnover of the paid medical services market in Russia amounted to over 600 billion roubles in 2018, with market turnover growing at over 10% annually [52].
This set of institutional arrangements allows us to identify three sub-groups of the population: first, the largest group is reliant on MHI (supplemented where possible with out-of-pocket expenditure) only; second, is the group that receives supplemental VHI through association with their enterprise; and third, is the group that chooses to finance supplemental VHI themselves while still having access through MHI. Our interest is in observing how and whether membership of one or other of these insurance groupings impacts on health outcomes and health behaviours. These institutional configurations are helpful as they allow us to partially unpick some of the classical asymmetry of information challenges that characterise the relationship between health insurance, health outcomes and health behaviours. That is, although the three groups above are not mutually exclusive, we can identify two distinct ‘types’ of consumers—those that choose to purchase their own health insurance (as supplement to MHI) and those that have health insurance provided by their enterprises (as supplement to MHI). The price changes apply to both types but the mechanisms through which they are ‘selected’ for health insurance differ significantly. Therefore, while distinguishing either ex-post or ex-ante moral hazard from adverse selection is necessarily speculative in the case of those self-selecting into VHI, we argue that in the case of enterprise provided insurance, adverse selection is negligible, an argument that also receives support from US based studies [53]. Given the importance of this latter assumption, we discuss this ‘selection mechanism’ further in “Data and empirical methodology”.
Russia now finds itself at a crossroads. There is widespread recognition that the prevailing system of compulsory medical insurance is ineffective and that the share of private spending on health care, between 40 and 50%, is too high. The Covid-19 pandemic has further exposed some of the weaknesses in the system of financing. A number of policy proposals remain on the table, ranging from the replacement of the mandatory system with a purely voluntary system, the introduction of a co-payment system, the development of a comprehensive drug insurance system, or the further reduction of the mandatory offer alongside a more clearly differentiated expansion of the voluntary system. The research in this paper advances the understanding of where the inefficiencies lie, both in the mandatory and the voluntary health financing systems.

Data and empirical methodology

Data

This research draws on Phase II of the RLMS-HSE,2 which is a series of annual household surveys designed to monitor the health and economic welfare of households and individuals in Russia. Data has been collected each autumn since 1994 (other than in 1997 and 1999) and represents the only long-term, nationally representative, source of household and individual level data for the Russian Federation. In this paper we use the adult survey data from 2000 to 2017 inclusive (the years when information about VHI is included in the survey), restricting our sample to adults above mandatory schooling age (17) and up to age 72, beyond which labour market engagement is limited.3
The survey, which takes place each autumn, is based on the principle of ‘repeated sampling of dwellings’, in which all household members are interviewed in each survey (if they can be contacted within three visits), and then the dwelling itself (rather than the household) is followed over time. In combination with regular annual replenishments this sampling strategy maintains the cross-sectional representativeness of the sample for each round. Additionally, there is a component of the panel which is followed regardless of dwelling, and further attempts are also made to follow-up individuals who have moved out of the household. The round-by-round attrition, at a little under 10%, is not out of line with equivalent household panel surveys from elsewhere [54], while the 97% response rate of individuals within surveyed households is testament to the robustness of the survey protocol. The relative richness and reliability of these data allows us to draw on their longitudinal component to explore the relationship between VHI and health-related behaviours and outcomes, including as these are conditioned by important socio-economic and demographic heterogeneities.
We identify eight health outcome and behaviour (dependent) variables as well as a rich range of explanatory variables, including the VHI indicator. Full variable definitions are provided in Table 3. The first dependent variable, ‘visits to doctor’, is a variable with five categories, increasing sequentially from ‘less than annually’ through to ‘several times per month’ and represents a proxy for individual interaction with the health care system. This question has only featured in the RLMS-HSE survey since 2004, so the corresponding estimates refer to a slightly reduced sample. There are then 6 variables which proxy for individual health behaviours: smoking or not; quantity of cigarettes smoked among the sub-set of smokers; drinking or not; frequency of alcohol consumed among the sub-set of drinkers; regularity of physical exercise (question not included in the 2007 survey); and body mass index (BMI), disaggregated into deciles, as a proxy for health outcomes concerned with under- and overweight. Finally, self-assessed health (SAH) is a standard survey variable reflecting an individual’s assessment of their own overall health state on a 5-point scale, ranging from very bad to very good.
The main explanatory variable of interest is drawn from a question, included in the RLMS-HSE survey since 2000, asking if individuals have supplementary VHI. Respondents were subsequently asked whether they had paid for the VHI themselves, whether their enterprise/organisation had paid, or whether it was financed through some ‘other’ source. The share of VHI contracts paid by enterprises is approximately 80%, though higher in Moscow and St. Petersburg.4 In addition, we include a standard set of explanatory variables which are theoretically and empirically linked with health outcomes. At the individual level we control for log of monthly income measured in (Moscow, December 2006) roubles, the highest level of education achieved, and self-reported chronic illness (specifically heart, lung, kidney, liver, spinal or gastrointestinal). Income and education are traditional controls in so far as they determine access to and knowledge of medical services and healthy lifestyles. Table 4 demonstrates that the mean values of health indicators are different over respondents’ education levels, while Table 5 confirms, as expected, that chronic illness is a significant predictor of the dependent variables. At the household level, we follow the literature [39, 55, 56], in controlling for the presence of children aged under three, as a proxy for ‘young family’ status, and Table 5, shows that, in most cases, the mean values of healthy life indicators for people with children differ significantly from those without young children. At the macro level we control for year fixed effects to capture the influence of aggregate time trends.
Table 1 presents descriptive statistics for the dependent and explanatory variables according to whether the individual respondent reports having no VHI, having enterprise VHI (ever during 2000–2017 and concurrently with the response year), or having self-provided VHI (ever during 2000–2017 and concurrently with the response year). Those with enterprise VHI comprise of more males, are richer, report fewer chronic illnesses, have more young children and are more likely to be located in Moscow and St. Petersburg. They are more educated than those who never had VHI during the period but marginally less educated than those who are self-insured. Compared to those with no VHI, the latter are less male but richer, more educated and with more chronic illness reported. Turning to the eight health outcomes of interest, those without VHI have the lowest number of visits to the doctor, the lowest propensity to drink but also the lowest engagement with physical exercise and the lowest self-assessment of their health status. Comparing enterprise and self-provided VHI, visits to the doctor and physical exercise are lower among the former, but smoking, drinking and BMI are all higher. Self-assessed health is higher among those currently reporting VHI but lower among those ever having reported VHI.
Table 1
Descriptive statistics (mean values, standard deviations, number of observations, and number of respondents)
Variables (short notation in brackets)
Statistical notations
Without VHI from 2000 to 2017
Ever self, but not now
Ever enterprise, but not now
In years of self
In years of enterprise
(1) Visits to doctor (doctor)
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
2.190 (0.880; 0.727)
2.254 (0.821; 0.774)
2.232 (0.761; 0.754)
2.527 (1.053; 0.404)
2.387 (0.903; 0.596)
Observations; respondents
132,424; 28,336
5047; 801
15,510; 2785
867; 658
5877; 2827
(2) Smoker (smoke)
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
0.346 (0.453; 0.188)
0.325 (0.415; 0.224)
0.370 (0.444; 0.214)
0.305 (0.463; 0.077)
0.374 (0.471; 0.163)
Observations; respondents
159,430; 31,618
6102; 844
18,889; 2932
1030; 769
6615; 3177
(3) Cigarette consumption (smoke_n)
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
15.450 (7.065; 4.535)
15.447 (7.097; 4.811)
15.383 (6.872; 4.662)
14.907 (7.639; 1.741)
15.714 (7.754; 3.090)
Observations; respondents
54,402; 13,261
1960; 342
6939; 1384
311; 247
2451; 1296
(4) Drink (drink)
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
0.710 (0.385; 0.288)
0.706 (0.373; 0.279)
0.790 (0.317; 0.276)
0.850 (0.380; 0.068)
0.840 (0.335; 0.197)
Observations; respondents
121,704; 26,914
4593; 777
13,789; 2687
782; 596
5549; 2713
(5) Alcohol consumption (drink_n)
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
2.417 (0.997; 0.736)
2.555 (0.971; 0.776)
2.548 (0.928; 0.774)
2.533 (1.158; 0.431)
2.584 (1.073; 0.594)
Observations; respondents
84,789; 22,916
3538; 683
12,370; 2558
709; 518
4788; 2506
(6) Physical exercise (sport)
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
1.518 (0.958; 0.809)
1.689 (0.903; 0.975)
1.607 (0.875; 0.878)
1.780 (1.246; 0.415)
1.733 (1.126; 0.730)
Observations; respondents
149,416; 31,218
5723; 840
17,608; 2908
891; 667
6006; 2971
(7) BMI decile (bmi_dec)
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
5.445 (2.692; 1.167)
5.510 (2.610; 1.259)
5.553 (2.669; 1.170)
5.415 (2.816; 0.456)
5.699 (2.768; 0.784)
Observations; respondents
159,518; 31,621
6107; 844
18,903; 2932
1031; 770
6617; 3177
(8) SAH (sah)
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
3.260 (0.629; 0.414)
3.368 (0.543; 0.439)
3.344 (0.486; 0.424)
3.310 (0.624; 0.166)
3.372 (0.573; 0.305)
Observations; respondents
158,724; 31,576
6078; 844
18,818; 2931
1027; 766
6596; 3170
(9) Log (1 + Income)
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
7.984 (2.683; 2.138)
8.256 (2.364; 2.322)
8.762 (1.827; 2.051)
8.781 (2.515; 0.767)
9.631 (1.613; 1.023)
Observations; respondents
159,518; 31,621
6107; 844
18,903; 2932
1031; 770
6617; 3177
(10) Secondary school
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
0.240 (0.444; 0.132)
0.153 (0.374; 0.154)
0.120 (0.308; 0.134)
0.138 (0.365; 0.031)
0.087 (0.301; 0.063)
Observations; respondents
159,518; 31,621
6107; 844
18,903; 2932
1031; 770
6617; 3177
(11) Vocational training school
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
0.224 (0.401; 0.068)
0.160 (0.338; 0.074)
0.200 (0.376; 0.085)
0.138 (0.350; 0.000)
0.163 (0.375; 0.046)
Observations; respondents
159,518; 31,621
6107; 844
18,903; 2932
1031; 770
6617; 3177
(12) Technical college
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
0.274 (0.417; 0.113)
0.244 (0.398; 0.140)
0.273 (0.420; 0.144)
0.229 (0.420; 0.062)
0.257 (0.432; 0.092)
Observations; respondents
159,518; 31,621
6107; 844
18,903; 2932
1031; 770
6617; 3177
(13) University
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
0.262 (0.422; 0.125)
0.443 (0.473; 0.170)
0.407 (0.473; 0.168)
0.496 (0.497; 0.062)
0.493 (0.493; 0.107)
Observations; respondents
159,518; 31,621
6107; 844
18,903; 2932
1031; 770
6617; 3177
(14) Chronic disease
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
0.389 (0.415; 0.298)
0.403 (0.400; 0.322)
0.373 (0.386; 0.319)
0.473 (0.486; 0.166)
0.372 (0.452; 0.231)
Observations; respondents
159,518; 31,621
6107; 844
18,903; 2932
1031; 770
6617; 3177
(15) Children < 3 years in HH
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
0.117 (0.267; 0.243)
0.120 (0.234; 0.264)
0.130 (0.252; 0.274)
0.099 (0.315; 0.093)
0.143 (0.308; 0.218)
Observations; respondents
159,518; 31,621
6107; 844
18,903; 2932
1031; 770
6617; 3177
(16) = 1 if age < 36
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
0.393 (0.481; 0.186)
0.442 (0.460; 0.238)
0.404 (0.455; 0.242)
0.415 (0.493; 0.115)
0.421 (0.485; 0.167)
Observations; respondents
159,518; 31,621
6107; 844
18,903; 2932
1031; 770
6617; 3177
(17) Male
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
0.423 (0.498; 0.000)
0.443 (0.497; 0.000)
0.497 (0.500; 0.000)
0.400 (0.496; 0.000)
0.523 (0.499; 0.000)
Observations; respondents
159,518; 31,621
6107; 844
18,903; 2932
1031; 770
6617; 3177
(18) = 1 if low education (less than university)
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
0.738 (0.422; 0.125)
0.557 (0.473; 0.170)
0.593 (0.473; 0.168)
0.504 (0.497; 0.062)
0.507 (0.493; 0.107)
Observations; respondents
159,518; 31,621
6107; 844
18,903; 2932
1031; 770
6617; 3177
(19) = 1 if Moscow or St. Petersburg
Mean (S.d. between; S.d. within)
0.106 (0.342; 0.000)
0.103 (0.322; 0.000)
0.170 (0.413; 0.000)
0.136 (0.335; 0.000)
0.212 (0.421; 0.000)
Observations; respondents
159,518; 31,621
6107; 844
18,903; 2932
1031; 770
6617; 3177
For variables (1)–(8) statistics refer to the corresponding number of non-missing values included in the estimates reported in Table 2 (male and female sample)
For variables (9)–(19), we use the (male and female) sample corresponding to that reported in Table 2 for “bmi_dec”
To further understand the data, in Figs. 1 and 2, we present cumulative hazard functions, taking into account that we have left truncation of VHI in our data. The hazard functions are estimated on the sample of observations for which we have non-missing values of the explanatory variables and which we use in our subsequent regression estimates. Figure 1 confirms that respondents have a greater chance of leaving an uninsured state for enterprise provided VHI rather than for self-funded VHI. Figure 2 suggests that there is slightly greater persistence in the enterprise funded case and that the differences become noticeable after 10 years. Table 6 illustrates that the sample churning (e.g., major sample changes in 2001, 2006, 2010 and 2014) and left and right censoring would render any single cumulative hazard curve (i.e., not considered in comparison) largely meaningless. However, for our purposes, where we compare the behaviour associated with two contract types, the long panel component of the RLMS-HSE data facilitates analysis in which we can control for time invariant individual unobservable characteristics using fixed effects (FE) models. Moreover, as Table 7 shows, insurance episodes tend to be of short duration (i.e., less than 3 years) which, combined with the churning evident in Table 6, means that we observe substantial within variation of the corresponding explanatory variables, allowing us to reliably estimate the correlation between insurance status and a range of potential moral hazard behaviours.

Methods

The descriptive statistics, discussed above, begin to reveal a pattern across health outcomes and behaviours. However, evaluating impact effects based on the comparison of simple descriptive statistics overlooks the respondent specific characteristics, including environmental differences, which may be important drivers of health-related outcomes. To explore more systematically we use regression analysis, controlling for the observed confounding factors (income, education, chronic illness, children, year) described above. However, a further part of the between respondent variation in the outcome variables of interest could be due to unobserved confounders. To the extent that such factors are individual time-invariant we can control for any consequent bias using the deviations from the individual means of variables in the FE regression models. In the regression models, with various health indicators as dependent variables, \(self\) and \(ent\) are the key (binary) variables of interest. For this approach to be valid, we rely on the assumption that the trend behaviour across different categories is consistent across time, regardless of movement between categories. To guard against the possibility that this may not hold, as a robustness check, we repeat estimates for different samples, defined according to age, gender, education, region and, finally, without the respondents who were never insured in the period 2000–2017.
We estimate eight FE base regressions (corresponding to the eight dependent variables):
$$y_{it} = \alpha_{i} + \beta_{1} {\text{self}}_{it} + \beta_{2} {\text{ent}}_{it} + x^{\prime}_{it} \delta + \mu_{t} + \varepsilon_{it} ,$$
(1)
where \(y_{it}\) is the response of individual \(i\) in period \(t\) to questions relating to the eight dependent variables; \(x_{it} = (x_{1it} {\kern 1pt} x_{2it} \ldots x_{kit} )^{\prime}\) is the column-vector of the \(k\) control variables (income, education, chronic illness, presence of children under 3 years in household); \(\beta\)s are the main parameters of interest (revealing the excess in the mean value of the dependent variable, \(y\), for the corresponding insurance state in comparison with the uninsured state, holding all other control variables, time, and individual effects fixed); \(\delta\) is a column-vector of parameters for the control variables; \(\alpha_{i}\) is the respondents’ time invariant individual-specific unobservable characteristics (that could correlate with regressors); \(\mu_{t}\) is time fixed effects; and \(\varepsilon_{it}\) is the error term that captures unobservable individual and environmental characteristics that may vary between respondents and over years. We first estimate each base model regression for the full pooled sample, before then re-estimating for different sub-samples defined according to age, gender, education and region.
We then repeat this exercise in what amounts to an extensive series of robustness checks. First, we simply exclude from the sample those respondents who never had any form of VHI. Second, we estimate FE logit models for the binary dependent variables (‘smoke’ and ‘drink’):
$$\Pr (y_{it} = 1|{\text{self}}_{it} ,{\text{ent}}_{it} ,x_{it} ) = \Lambda (\alpha_{i} + \beta_{1} {\text{self}}_{it} + \beta_{2} {\text{ent}}_{it} + x^{\prime}_{it} \delta + \mu_{t} ),$$
(2)
where \(\Lambda\) is the cumulative logistic distribution. Third, given the ordered choice nature of five of the dependent variables (doctor, drink_n, sport, bmi_dec, and sah), we might consider estimating the corresponding FE ordered choice logit:
$$\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {y_{it}^{*} = \alpha_{i} + \beta_{1} {\text{self}}_{it} + \beta_{2} {\text{ent}}_{it} + x^{\prime}_{it} \delta + \mu_{t} + \varepsilon_{it} ,\quad i = 1,2, \ldots ,n,\quad t = 1,2, \ldots ,T,} \hfill \\ {y_{it} = j,\quad \gamma_{{i{\kern 1pt} j - 1}} < y_{it}^{*} \le \gamma_{ij} ,\quad j = 1,2, \ldots ,M - 1,\quad \gamma_{i0} = - \infty ,\quad \gamma_{iM} = \infty ,} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(3)
where \(y_{it}^{*}\) in each model is one of the five latent variables which theoretically depend on the individual utility function values concerned with the respondent’s choice of the frequency of visits to doctor, alcohol consumption, level of physical activity, BMI decile, and self-assessed health;\(y_{it}\) is the respondent’s answer to the corresponding ordered choice question or BMI decile; and \(M\) is the number of possible responses from which respondents choose the \(j\)-th response (or else is mechanically located in the \(j\)-th BMI decile).
Unfortunately, in the case of the non-linear FE model (3), the \(\hat{\beta }\) estimates derived from short panels are inconsistent due to the so-called ‘incidental parameters problem’ [57, 58], when estimating the \(\gamma_{ij} - \alpha_{i}\) differences necessary to obtain the \(\hat{\beta }\)’s. Without being able to ‘naturally’ extend \(T\) we attenuate the inconsistencies in our \(\hat{\beta }\) estimates through the application of a ‘BUC’ (Blow up and Cluster) methodology. In this approach we replace each observation in the sample by \(M - 1\) copies of itself (so-called ‘Blow-Ups’) and each of these \(M - 1\) replications of the individual’s choice is dichotomised at a different cut-off point \(\gamma_{ij}\). Crucially, this process of dichotomisation, which preserves as much information as possible concerning the changes in the dependent variable, means the BUC methodology is robust to finite samples [3] and is well suited to our data. The \(\beta\) parameters, for each specification of Eq. (3), are estimated by the conditional logit model on the ‘blown up’ sample, clustering the standard errors according to the \(i\) individuals and removing the need to estimate \(\alpha_{i}\).

The selection mechanism

At the core of this research lies the identifying assumption that there is no systematic selection mechanism at work in the way that individuals become associated with enterprise provided VHI. Given the pre-eminence of this assumption it merits further elaboration before we present our results, with respect to both the institutional framework prevailing in Russia and to the empirical stylised facts in the Russian data. As we have seen, accounting for just 5.4% of all medical appointments, VHI remains relatively niche in Russia. Most Russian citizens have little familiarity with insurance principles in general and very limited understanding of the benefits associated with VHI services. In part this reflects the absence of clear legislation separating the varieties of service available through VHI and MHI and in part, reflects the restrictions within VHI contracts themselves. Specifically, the contracts are limiting in terms of the range of services, the range of locations and the quantity of doctors and specialists, but most significantly, they do not cover the (significant) costs of prescribed medication.
From the companies’ perspective, there are substantive benefits from offering VHI contracts to employees. These include benefits (up to 6% of payroll budget) relating to salary payments, exemptions from social taxes on VHI contract payments, and exemptions from personal and value added tax on the premiums and benefits associated with VHI. Large corporations, particularly in Moscow and St. Petersburg—where the health care market is more developed—therefore, face strong incentives to offer VHI as part of the employment package. Notwithstanding these incentives, there is little to suggest that Russian job seekers place high value on the provision of supplementary health insurance. Recent surveys by two of Russia’s largest employment agencies, Headhunter and Superjob, confirm that salary, job prospects, job stability, work environment, colleagues, location and the nature of the work are all seen, by job seekers, as more important than any accompanying social package, which may include VHI.5
We consider that this restrictive institutional setting renders it very unlikely that enterprise provided VHI suffers from the kind of adverse selection that we may expect in more mature health markets. However, even for the US, the evidence suggests that adverse selection is unlikely to be a significant issue for employer-provided insurance [53]. Nevertheless, to reassure ourselves further about this, we examine the empirical regularities within the RLMS-HSE data for evidence of adverse selection.
Specifically, we construct five binary health indicators comprising of: self-assessed health (1 if SAH is average, good, or very good); health problems in the last 30 days; hospitalisation during the previous 3 months; operation during the last 12 months; whether the household faces financial constraints in obtaining treatment/medicine; and three (log) real income/expenditure variables: per capita household spending on medical services; per capita household spending on medicine; and total individual income received in the last 30 days. We then implement a series of t tests comparing the means of these indicators across two groups: those in employment who had no VHI in period t and changed their place of work during the subsequent year for employment in t + 1 that (1) included VHI and (2) did not include VHI. We then repeat this exercise for those who were not in employment (including secondary employment) in period t. The results (Tables 8, 9, 10, 11) reveal no systematic evidence of adverse selection into employer provided VHI. If anything, the results demonstrate that workers changing jobs are healthier and financially better equipped to undertake health expenditure.6
In sum, while we do not claim to have a perfect natural experiment, our understanding of the Russian institutional context and the stylised facts that we observe in the data provide for both strong arguments and empirical evidence that Russian workers do not choose their employer based on the expectation of receiving VHI. This being so, we are confident that we can distinguish the effects of post-contract opportunist behaviour from adverse selection and can compare pre- and post-contract behaviours and outcomes across groups. To this end, Russia follows France [24] in providing a rare opportunity to contribute robustly to a US-centric literature with a European example.

Empirical results

Table 2 presents the \(\beta_{1}\) and \(\beta_{2}\) estimates and their ratios of separate regression estimates for the eight dependent variables, each, in turn, estimated on the total pooled sample and then on sub-samples defined by age (17–35; 36–72), gender (male; female), education (low; high) and region (Moscow/St. Petersburg; other regions). Tables 12, 13 and 14 present the corresponding equivalent estimates for our battery of robustness checks.
Table 2
\(\beta_{1}\) and \(\beta_{2}\) estimates and their ratios in FE models
 
Doctor
Smoke
Smoke_n
Drink
Drink_n
Sport
bmi_dec
sah
Male and female
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.220*** (0.034)
− 0.012 (0.008)
0.275 (0.361)
0.061*** (0.014)
0.025 (0.041)
0.054 (0.038)
− 0.115* (0.048)
− 0.020 (0.017)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.143*** (0.015)
− 0.001 (0.004)
0.387** (0.149)
0.022*** (0.006)
0.045* (0.018)
0.045** (0.017)
0.058** (0.022)
− 0.006 (0.008)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.650** (0.122)
0.074** (0.318)
1.405 (1.922)
0.360*** (0.132)
1.793 (2.997)
0.824 (0.652)
− 0.505 (0.286)
0.288 (0.462)
 Observations
159,803
192,079
65,744
146,578
105,496
179,681
192,193
191,255
 Respondents
32,486
35,970
15,251
30,935
26,688
35,547
35,974
35,929
Age 17–35
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.287*** (0.054)
− 0.033* (0.014)
0.168 (0.526)
0.069** (0.022)
0.029 (0.064)
0.002 (0.064)
− 0.173* (0.084)
− 0.041 (0.027)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.175*** (0.025)
− 0.004 (0.007)
0.174 (0.210)
0.024* (0.010)
0.041 (0.028)
0.063* (0.028)
0.090* (0.039)
− 0.015 (0.012)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.608** (0.143)
0.120*** (0.209)
1.035 (3.466)
0.343*** (0.182)
1.421 (3.324)
27.420 (770.321)
− 0.518 (0.333)
0.370+ (0.391)
 Observations
63,250
76,204
29,074
57,666
43,735
71,069
76,274
75,958
 Respondents
16,539
18,645
8633
15,521
13,707
18,365
18,649
18,627
Age 36–72
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.189*** (0.044)
0.001 (0.009)
0.139 (0.500)
0.052** (0.019)
0.029 (0.054)
0.092 (0.047)
− 0.034 (0.059)
− 0.013 (0.022)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.114*** (0.020)
0.000 (0.004)
0.455* (0.215)
0.016* (0.008)
0.049* (0.025)
0.048* (0.021)
0.022 (0.027)
− 0.004 (0.010)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.606* (0.179)
0.186 (4.247)
3.271 (11.863)
0.318*** (0.199)
1.699 (3.287)
0.523 (0.354)
− 0.653 (1.376)
0.306 (0.959)
 Observations
96,553
115,875
36,670
88,912
61,761
108,612
115,919
115,297
 Respondents
19,083
21,117
8303
18,256
15,649
20,924
21,117
21,090
Male
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.114* (0.050)
− 0.012 (0.015)
0.293 (0.468)
0.056** (0.021)
0.035 (0.066)
0.061 (0.061)
− 0.111 (0.081)
− 0.019 (0.027)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.156*** (0.020)
0.001 (0.006)
0.439* (0.183)
0.006 (0.008)
0.059* (0.026)
0.043 (0.024)
0.065* (0.033)
− 0.004 (0.011)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
1.372 (0.635)
− 0.060 (0.486)
1.501 (2.477)
0.107*** (0.150)
1.670 (3.235)
0.717 (0.819)
− 0.592 (0.524)
0.190 (0.642)
 Observations
68,931
83,274
47,562
63,384
54,086
77,888
83,311
82,876
 Respondents
14,771
16,484
10,698
14,015
13,322
16,288
16,486
16,465
Female
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.290*** (0.045)
− 0.011 (0.009)
0.180 (0.510)
0.063*** (0.019)
0.016 (0.049)
0.049 (0.048)
− 0.118* (0.060)
− 0.021 (0.021)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.131*** (0.023)
− 0.004 (0.004)
0.138 (0.241)
0.038*** (0.009)
0.026 (0.025)
0.046 (0.024)
0.051 (0.030)
− 0.008 (0.011)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.454*** (0.106)
0.317 (0.466)
0.764 (2.560)
0.598 (0.235)
1.565 (4.917)
0.949 (1.062)
− 0.430* (0.332)
0.376 (0.645)
 Observations
90,872
108,805
18,182
83,194
51,410
101,793
108,882
108,379
 Respondents
17,715
19,486
4553
16,920
13,366
19,259
19,488
19,464
Low education
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.173*** (0.049)
− 0.012 (0.011)
0.361 (0.479)
0.065** (0.021)
0.022 (0.061)
0.083 (0.051)
− 0.210** (0.071)
− 0.064** (0.024)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.119*** (0.022)
0.001 (0.005)
0.551** (0.190)
0.026** (0.009)
0.046 (0.025)
0.064** (0.022)
0.041 (0.031)
0.004 (0.011)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.689 (0.232)
− 0.126 (0.452)
1.526 (2.089)
0.400** (0.188)
2.078 (5.807)
0.762 (0.536)
− 0.197*** (0.163)
− 0.069*** (0.171)
 Observations
112,021
137,010
51,820
102,074
73,272
128,141
137,098
136,415
 Respondents
24,202
27,315
12,273
22,814
19,603
26,965
27,319
27,283
High education
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.256*** (0.047)
− 0.011 (0.011)
0.004 (0.540)
0.053** (0.019)
0.028 (0.054)
0.025 (0.060)
− 0.014 (0.063)
0.019 (0.024)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.153*** (0.022)
− 0.003 (0.005)
0.259 (0.243)
0.021* (0.009)
0.062* (0.026)
0.016 (0.028)
0.064* (0.030)
− 0.023* (0.011)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.596** (0.141)
0.257 (0.529)
63.487 (8399.449)
0.396** (0.221)
2.170 (4.233)
0.625 (1.833)
− 4.649 (21.430)
− 1.193 (1.592)
 Observations
47,782
55,069
13,924
44,504
32,224
51,540
55,095
54,840
 Respondents
10,044
10,762
3500
9701
8410
10,632
10,763
10,753
Moscow/St Petersburg
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.359*** (0.093)
0.029 (0.023)
0.377 (1.055)
0.026 (0.039)
0.128 (0.112)
0.215* (0.107)
0.148 (0.127)
0.075 (0.047)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.216*** (0.037)
0.003 (0.009)
0.351 (0.322)
0.016 (0.015)
0.094* (0.043)
0.112** (0.040)
0.028 (0.047)
− 0.005 (0.018)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.603* (0.188)
0.088** (0.304)
0.930 (2.763)
0.614 (1.088)
0.733 (0.732)
0.521 (0.322)
0.188* (0.360)
− 0.071*** (0.237)
 Observations
18,085
22,044
8854
16,219
12,743
20,400
22,052
21,929
 Respondents
4456
5152
2388
4046
3937
5068
5154
5145
Other regions
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.193*** (0.036)
− 0.018* (0.008)
0.268 (0.385)
0.067*** (0.015)
0.008 (0.044)
0.028 (0.040)
− 0.156** (0.052)
− 0.034 (0.018)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.125*** (0.017)
− 0.002 (0.004)
0.406* (0.167)
0.024*** (0.007)
0.031 (0.020)
0.029 (0.018)
0.064** (0.025)
− 0.006 (0.009)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.648* (0.150)
0.098*** (0.234)
1.515 (2.254)
0.352*** (0.130)
4.004 (22.550)
1.048 (1.680)
− 0.413** (0.211)
0.168** (0.273)
 Observations
141,718
170,035
56,890
130,359
92,753
159,281
170,141
169,326
 Respondents
28,030
30,818
12,863
26,889
22,751
30,479
30,820
30,784
Standard errors in parentheses. The significance tests reported for the \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\) rows tests that the absolute value of the ratio equals one. *p  <  0.05, **p  < 0.01, ***p  < 0.001. Variable names defined in Table 3
Our first main finding is that the provision or purchase of supplemental VHI in Russia is strongly associated with an increase in health care utilisation. In all cases, other than for males, the effect is statistically significantly larger in the case of self-provision than in the case of enterprise provision. For males, there is no significant difference in the magnitude of effect. In both cases, the effects are strongest among younger cohorts, females, those with more education and those in Moscow and St. Petersburg. In each sub-group, the within sub-group differential is greater for the self-insured compared to the enterprise insured. The effects of self-provision are much larger for women, which is consistent with the much greater access to health care that Russian females have. Overall, these results suggest that, although the self-insured effects appear to conflate adverse selection with moral hazard, in Russia—as in most other countries for which evidence exists—there is strong overall evidence of ex-post moral hazard.
Turning to ex-ante moral hazard, the results are less clear-cut, but no less interesting. The impact of supplemental insurance on whether an individual smokes or not is negligible. There is weak evidence overall that those with self-funded insurance are less likely to smoke and that this appears to be primarily driven by younger cohorts and those outside of Moscow and St. Petersburg. More interesting are the results for smoking intensity, where we find strong evidence of higher smoking for enterprise-insurance types, with particularly strong effects for males, older cohorts, the less educated, and those outside of Moscow and St. Petersburg. Given that smoking in Russia remains a highly gendered habit [59], these results are predominantly reflective of male, rather than female, health behaviours.
The results for alcohol consumption do not mirror those for smoking. Insurance, whether self- or enterprise-funded, is strongly positively associated with the propensity to drink. The size of the effect is once again significantly larger among those self-insuring, suggesting that there is an element of adverse selection in addition to ex-ante moral hazard. This pattern is consistent across all sub-groups though the effect is not present for either form of insurance in Moscow and St. Petersburg. When it comes to drinking intensity, the results are striking. There is no relationship between self-insurance and the consumption of alcohol among drinkers but there is a significant positive relationship between enterprise insurance and consumption among drinkers. In combination, the drinking results suggest that the positive impact of insurance on the likelihood of drinking is greater for those with self-insurance but that the impact on the amount consumed is only observed among those with enterprise VHI.
Levels of physical exercise are positively associated with enterprise VHI in aggregate and specifically for those with lower education and in Moscow and St. Petersburg. In the latter case though, there is a still stronger effect among the self-insured. Those with self-insurance also have lower BMI, a result which sustains for the youngest cohorts, for females, for the less educated and for those outside of Moscow and St. Petersburg. In contrast, those with enterprise level insurance tend towards a higher BMI decile, a result which also pertains to younger cohorts, males and those in other Russian regions and to the more highly educated.
Finally, turning to self-assessed health, the results are weaker, though we still detect some effects. For the less educated we find some evidence that those with self-insurance report lower health status, while for individuals with enterprise VHI, we find that only those with higher education report lower levels of health.
Tables 12, 13 and 14 present the robustness checks described in the previous section. Table 12, in which we exclude from the sample those respondents who never had any form of VHI, shows that the pattern of \(\beta\) estimates, ratios and significant tests remains qualitatively similar to those reported in our main results. This reassures us that the impact of ex-ante moral hazard (if it is present among the insured respondents) is negligible. Similarly, the average marginal effects of regressors of interest, estimated under FE logit models, and their ratios, as well as the corresponding average marginal effects of BUC estimates, reveal no qualitative differences from our main results.
In the event that enterprise provided VHI does not cover all of the necessary medical expenses some respondents may also have self-provided VHI. Table 15 presents the number of these cases and so as a further robustness check, in Table 16, we repeat the estimates with these cases removed. A comparison of Table 16 with Table 2 shows that the results remain qualitatively the same, with the majority of \(\beta\) estimates increasing in magnitude with the ‘purer’ sample. Self-purchased and workplace provided VHI could be partially funded by others (for example, via intra-family transfers in the case of self-provision, or through banks, or government ministries in the case of enterprise provision) and so, as a final robustness check, we confirm that the tenor of the results, excluding the observations detailed in Table 17, do not change.
Finally, it is likely that employer provided health insurance is non-uniform across industry and occupation. Figures 3 and 4 confirm that, broadly speaking, there are higher rates of VHI among managers, professionals and technical occupations in the IT, finance, energy and marketing and advertising sectors but that this is true regardless of whether self-provided or enterprise provided. Likewise, given that we are interested in the effects on those that actually have VHI, we don’t require uniformity of provision (or take up) of VHI, although—in thinking about policy implications—understanding of these distributions is instructive.

Conclusions and discussion

The well-documented positive relationship between health insurance and health care utilisation has firmly established the existence of ex-post moral hazard as a necessary consideration to inform the design of health care systems and policies. In contrast, the theoretically and empirically ambiguous link between health insurance and preventative care use, risky health behaviours and health outcomes is a product of the specific institutional features of the health-care system and the social, economic and demographic characteristics within which it sits. Indeed, Harmon and Nolan [26] maintain that “the nature of demand for private health insurance itself depends on the institutional context in which that insurance operates”. This is an observation echoed in more recent studies discussing the mechanisms which may underpin the association between health insurance and health behaviours [4548]. In this spirit, we offer the first empirical investigation of moral hazard in the health insurance sector in Russia. We provide robust evidence of ex-post moral hazard and, in contrast to some other literature, evidence also of ex-ante moral hazard.
Applying a range of econometric techniques, including a novel ‘Blow-Up and Cluster’ approach, to Russian longitudinal data, we compare the impact of enterprise provided and individually purchased supplemental VHI on eight health-related dependent variables proxying for ex-post and ex-ante moral hazard, in addition to self-assessed health. While adverse selection will likely distort the estimated impact of self-funded health insurance on behaviours and outcomes, we provide empirical and contextual arguments as to why this is unlikely to be the case with enterprise provided health insurance in Russia. Therefore, while we do not have an experimental setting, we do have two differing insurance ‘types’ who form their sub-groups through distinct selection mechanisms and provide us with a rare European setting in which we can disentangle moral hazard and adverse selection.
We find strong evidence that, as elsewhere, ex-post moral hazard should be an important consideration in designing health care policy. Post-contract visits to the doctor are unambiguously higher for individuals with supplemental health insurance. This is true in the pooled sample, in all sub-samples and is robust to different econometric specifications and approaches. Consistent with our expectations, the effects are larger for those who have self-insured but this likely reflects their self-selection (adverse selection) into health insurance plans. Equivalent adverse selection is difficult to contemplate in the case of enterprise provided health care, which is not a determining factor in Russian workers choosing their employer. We are, therefore, confident that, compared to those without supplemental insurance, Russian workers with enterprise provided insurance have engaged with the health care sector more regularly. In short, we concur with Einav and Finkelstein [15] that moral hazard, of the ex-post variety, “irrefutably exists”.
Consistent with the ambiguous theoretical predictions concerning ex-ante moral hazard our findings are less conclusive but are strongly suggestive of links between supplemental health insurance and ex-ante health behaviours and are more contingent on population demographics than our previous findings. The over and misuse of alcohol and tobacco, poor nutrition and diets, and a lack of physical exercise are notorious public health challenges in Russia and are major sources of mortality and morbidity, particularly among males. We find that those with self-insurance are less inclined to smoke than those with no insurance, they are more likely to be drinkers, but not to have higher consumption of alcohol, they have greater engagement with physical exercise and have lower BMI. In contrast, compared to those without insurance, individuals with enterprise VHI smoke more (particularly males, older cohorts, the less educated and those in the Russian regions), drink more (other than females) have higher BMI (other than older, more educated cohorts, in Moscow and St. Petersburg), and while their physical exercise is greater, it is less high than for those with self-provided VHI. In aggregate, we interpret these findings as strongly suggestive of an association between enterprise VHI and ex-ante moral hazard that is not observed among those who self-provide their VHI.
The net effect of insurance on health outcomes depends on the changes in both access to care and in health behaviours and, therefore, is theoretically ambiguous. The extent to which insurance-induced increases in health care utilisation translate to better health depends on the individual’s initial location along the health production function and on whether any changes in their health behaviours contribute to health improvements or, in the case of moral hazard, are linked with health deterioration. Our data offer us limited scope to explore health outcomes, beyond those that we control for in the regressions, but we find only limited evidence of a systematic relationship with self-assessed health (a reliable predictor of health outcomes). Ambiguity in these effects is consistent with findings from, for example, the RAND health insurance experiment and likely reflects that insurance can have positive effects for those that self-select into it (e.g., the chronically ill) but that these are offset by the negative impact that the need to self-select has in the first place.
In exploring whether and how these patterns vary according to population sub-group we are constrained somewhat by the number of observations, and our findings are, therefore, only suggestive. We do though discern clear patterns according to age, education, location and gender which are consistent with our understanding of the Russian context. In particular, health care infrastructure and insurance markets are more developed in Moscow and St. Petersburg, Russian women are much more likely to utilise health services and, in taking out health insurance, they have in mind their future engagement with health care services.
In Russia, as elsewhere, there is ongoing discussion concerning the role of supplemental insurance schemes aimed at expanding access to health care outside of the increasingly pressured core provision financed through mandatory health insurance. Our results make clear that insurance increases health care utilisation and increases unhealthy behaviours, albeit to different extents for different population sub-groups, but that it has no discernible impact upon immediate population health outcomes.
The tentative findings concerning ex-ante moral hazard are consistent with some of those emanating from the recent empirical literature from myriad jurisdictions, including the US [31, 39], Europe [60] and China [45, 47, 61]. The latter [61], finding strong evidence of ex-ante moral hazard in rural China, also provides a review of the literature from diverse developing countries which suggests that insurance-induced lifestyle changes impact indirectly on individual health through the behavioural changes induced via the provision of insurance. These changes in turn, may stem from differential access to health promotion and/or simply more regular contact with health professionals [31].
The finding that, separately from ex-post moral hazard, health insurance induces lifestyle changes that can damage individual health and undermine the public health system is self-evidently important in so far as it adds to the potential obstacles to achieving universal health coverage [62]. From a practical policy perspective, it suggests that the efficiency gains from understanding the effects of health insurance policies may be even greater than has been assumed. Indeed, understanding how co-payments and deductibles might lower health expenditure and reduce ex-post moral hazard is an empirical question facing all health insurance systems. However, there is growing evidence—including in this paper—that other policy tools (e.g., risk-rated premiums; or subsidised physician counselling and health promotion) targeting lifestyle behaviours could also increase efficiency and social welfare by attenuating distortions that health insurance introduces. In short, we have provided evidence that, in Russia—as elsewhere—insurance can shape behavioural impulses and so policy innovations targeting particular population sub-groups and behaviours such as excess consumption of tobacco and alcohol and incentivising improved nutrition and physical exercise will increase the efficiency of insurance policies and contribute to improved public health.
While we have contemplated the direction in which policy might look, this research also poses a series of questions that require further interrogation: Do the benefits of greater health care use outweigh the incentives to engage more freely in risky behaviours? Does enterprise provided insurance encourage those that under-use health care services (e.g., males, low income groups) to increase their utilisation and thereby positively address health inequalities? Why (in these data) is self-funded health insurance associated with reduced BMI but enterprise provided insurance linked with increased BMI? How can insurance plans simultaneously increase access to health care while also incentivising health behaviours that reduce the likelihood of health care being needed? As all countries confront the challenge of obtaining greater value from the resources they devote to health care, these questions and discerning credible answers to them become increasingly important. Far from being Russia-specific, our findings serve to emphasise the range of empirical questions that are pertinent to each contextual and institutional setting.
In addition to raising several crucial policy-related questions, several caveats to our analysis provide additional directions for future research. First, exploring a wider range of subjective, objective and clinical health outcomes is important for better understanding the ‘benefit’ side of supplemental health insurance. Second, examining changes in behaviour separately for those that do and do not already engage with the health system may provide further insight into the nature of moral hazard in Russian health care. Third, we take no account of expenditure or price data and thus are unable to disentangle income and price effects. Finally, collecting more nuanced insurance (e.g., across different contract types) and health data in Russia on a larger scale, particularly so that further sub-group analysis can be developed, will increase the power of the analysis and help to shed light on the mechanisms through which insurance and health-related behaviours are linked. This in turn will help us to understand where insurance expansion can be most beneficial and what kind of incentives should be built into its provision.
Open AccessThis article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Unsere Produktempfehlungen

Neuer Inhalt

Print-Titel

e.Med Interdisziplinär

Kombi-Abonnement

Für Ihren Erfolg in Klinik und Praxis - Die beste Hilfe in Ihrem Arbeitsalltag

Mit e.Med Interdisziplinär erhalten Sie Zugang zu allen CME-Fortbildungen und Fachzeitschriften auf SpringerMedizin.de.

Anhänge

Appendix

See Figs. 1, 2, 3 and 4 and Tables 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, 13, 14, 15, 16 and 17.
Table 3
Variable definitions and their short notations (in brackets)
Variable name
Variable definition
Visits to doctor (doctor)
1, < annually; 2, annually; 3, 2–3 times a year; 4, monthly; 5, several times per month
Smoker (smoke)
1 if a respondent smokes, 0 otherwise
Cigarette consumption (smoke_n)
Number of cigarettes smoked per day by those who smoke
Drink (drink)
1 if a respondent ever drinks, 0 otherwise
Alcohol consumption (drink_n)
1, once last month; 2, 2–3 times last month; 3, weekly; 4, 2–3 times a week; 5, 4–6 times a week; 6, daily
Physical exercise (sport)
1, none; 2, light exercise; 3, moderate exercise; 4, intensive exercise; 5, daily
BMI decile (bmi_dec)
Body mass index as categorical variable representing deciles
SAH (sah)
Self-assessed health: 1, very bad; 2, bad; 3, average; 4, good; 5, very good
Log (1 + income)
The natural logarithm of respondent’s monthly income (+ 1) in Moscow Dec. 2006 rubles
Education
Defined by 4 dummy variables for: secondary school, vocational training school, technical college and university
Chronic disease
Self-reported heart, lung, kidney, liver, spinal or gastrointestinal disease
Children < 3 years in HH
1 if household has children under 3 years, 0 otherwise
Sub-samples grouped by
 = 1 if age < 36
1 if age below 36 years, 0 otherwise
Male
1 if male, 0 if female
 = 1 if low education
1 if less than university education, 0 otherwise
 = 1 if Moscow or St. Petersburg
1 if in Moscow or St. Petersburg, 0 otherwise
Table 4
Mean values of health indicators by education
Indicator
Secondary school
Vocational training school
Technical college
University
\(\chi^{2}\)
Visits to doctor (doctor)
2.154 (0.006)
2.065 (0.006)
2.240 (0.005)
2.289 (0.005)
1074.7***
Smoker (smoke)
0.336 (0.002)
0.518 (0.002)
0.312 (0.002)
0.257 (0.002)
7707.2***
Cigarette consumption (smoke_n)
15.576 (0.066)
16.463 (0.054)
14.835 (0.061)
14.521 (0.065)
655.8***
Drink (drink)
0.615 (0.002)
0.753 (0.002)
0.730 (0.002)
0.758 (0.002)
2054.8***
Alcohol consumption (drink_n)
2.451 (0.008)
2.624 (0.007)
2.336 (0.007)
2.415 (0.006)
866.4***
Physical exercise (sport)
1.598 (0.006)
1.341 (0.006)
1.467 (0.005)
1.732 (0.005)
3275.0***
BMI decile (bmi_dec)
5.493
5.448
5.620
5.335
285.7***
(0.014)
(0.014)
(0.012)
(0.012)
SAH (sah)
3.298 (0.003)
3.246 (0.003)
3.232 (0.003)
3.339 (0.003)
884.5***
Standard error in parentheses; ***p < 0.001
Table 5
Mean values of health indicators by binary control variables
Indicator
Variable = 
1 (yes)
0 (no)
t st
Mean
St. err
Mean
St. err
Visits to doctor (doctor)
Chronic disease
2.522
0.004
2.002
0.003
96.58***
Children < 3 years in HH
2.173
0.008
2.203
0.003
− 3.71***
Smoker (smoke)
Chronic disease
0.321
0.002
0.361
0.001
− 18.64***
Children < 3 years in HH
0.375
0.003
0.342
0.001
9.75***
Cigarette consumption (smoke_n)
Chronic disease
15.970
0.054
15.162
0.037
12.33***
Children < 3 years in HH
15.153
0.083
15.496
0.033
− 3.86***
Drink (drink)
Chronic disease
0.710
0.002
0.725
0.001
− 6.19***
Children < 3 years in HH
0.715
0.003
0.720
0.001
− 1.42
Alcohol consumption (drink_n)
Chronic disease
2.393
0.006
2.482
0.004
− 12.15***
Children < 3 years in HH
2.418
0.010
2.454
0.004
− 3.42***
Physical exercise (sport)
Chronic disease
1.513
0.004
1.567
0.003
− 10.10***
Children < 3 years in HH
1.483
0.007
1.555
0.003
− 9.20***
BMI decile (bmi_dec)
Chronic disease
5.480
0.011
5.466
0.008
1.09
Children < 3 years in HH
5.668
0.019
5.445
0.007
11.14***
SAH (sah)
Chronic disease
2.906
0.002
3.516
0.002
− 211.81***
Children < 3 years in HH
3.464
0.004
3.256
0.002
46.27***
***p < 0.001
Table 6
Number of events in Nelson–Aalen cumulative hazard functions estimates (fail refers to end of spell)
Year
Self-funded VHI
Enterprise provided VHI
Uninsured spell (Table 4)
Insured spell (Table 5)
Uninsured spell (Table 4)
Insured spell (Table 5)
Fail
Lost
Enter
Fail
Lost
Enter
Fail
Lost
Enter
Fail
Lost
Enter
2000
22
6629
6026
115
5670
5089
102
102
102
104
5681
5096
2001
36
7236
6976
223
6110
5778
162
162
162
181
6158
5820
2002
39
7829
6986
116
6571
5826
129
129
129
109
6613
5864
2003
27
7624
7101
80
6422
5873
116
116
116
78
6461
5911
2004
26
7728
7083
103
6428
5781
83
83
83
109
6466
5811
2005
32
7377
7361
75
6081
6027
87
87
87
78
6102
6040
2006
31
9793
8945
323
8157
7348
182
182
182
263
8233
7412
2007
102
9609
8749
123
8020
7239
295
295
295
100
8100
7303
2008
20
9326
8588
86
7754
7075
220
220
220
79
7829
7133
2009
32
9245
8559
67
7686
7093
144
144
144
69
7742
7139
2010
80
14,301
12,087
547
12,320
10,237
259
259
259
447
12,470
10,358
2011
92
14,112
12,703
277
12,080
10,823
437
437
437
183
12,283
10,974
2012
63
14,703
12,746
194
12,695
10,890
253
253
253
179
12,852
11,016
2013
40
14,098
11,617
109
12,206
9947
168
168
168
128
12,320
10,044
2014
30
11,882
10,664
49
10,225
9110
131
131
131
58
10,321
9200
2015
28
11,822
10,834
41
10,212
9368
93
93
93
47
10,289
9430
2016
27
11,984
10,977
24
10,423
9569
97
97
97
42
10,476
9619
2017
28
12,165
0
33
10,672
0
111
111
111
24
10,740
0
Table 7
Cumulative years of each respondent insurance started and ended inside 2000–2017
Years
Self-funded VHI
Enterprise provided VHI
Frequency
Percent
Cumulative percent
Frequency
Percent
Cumulative percent
1
624
82.65
82.65
1708
61.95
61.95
2
76
10.07
92.72
508
18.43
80.38
3
28
3.71
96.42
252
9.14
89.52
4
14
1.85
98.28
130
4.72
94.23
5
1
0.13
98.41
57
2.07
96.30
6
7
0.93
99.34
37
1.34
97.64
7
3
0.40
99.74
26
0.94
98.59
8
1
0.13
99.87
16
0.58
99.17
9
1
0.13
100.00
8
0.29
99.46
10
   
6
0.22
99.67
11
   
6
0.22
99.89
12
   
2
0.07
99.96
13
      
14
   
1
0.04
100.00
Respondents
755
100.00
 
2757
100.00
 
Table 8
Selection tests for working males (*p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001)
Indicator
New job + VHI
New job, noVHI
t st
Mean
St. err
Mean
St. err
SAH binary
0.992
0.008
0.965
0.007
2.45*
No health problems
0.776
0.037
0.722
0.018
1.29
Not hospitalized
1.000
0.000
0.977
0.006
3.78***
No operation
0.984
0.011
0.963
0.008
1.59
HH has money for treatment and medicine
0.783
0.046
0.803
0.019
− 0.40
Log (1 + Medical treatment per HH capita, 30 days)
6.289
0.320
6.046
0.117
0.71
Log (1 + Medicine bought per HH capita, 30 days)
5.182
0.110
5.002
0.055
1.47
Log (1 + Income)
8.950
0.239
8.770
0.098
0.70
Table 9
Selection tests for working females (*p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001)
Indicator
New job + VHI
New job, noVHI
t st
Mean
St. err
Mean
St. err
SAH binary
0.961
0.019
0.962
0.008
− 0.07
No health problems
0.574
0.049
0.643
0.021
− 1.29
Not hospitalized
0.941
0.023
0.966
0.008
− 1.01
No operation
0.941
0.023
0.957
0.009
− 0.62
HH has money for treatment and medicine
0.795
0.046
0.773
0.021
0.44
Log (1 + Medical treatment per HH capita, 30 days)
6.003
0.279
5.967
0.136
0.12
Log (1 + Medicine bought per HH capita, 30 days)
5.356
0.144
5.088
0.063
1.70
Log (1 + Income)
9.153
0.154
8.491
0.098
3.63***
Table 10
Selection tests for non-working males (*p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001)
Indicator
Job with VHI
Job without VHI
t st
Mean
St. err
Mean
St. err
SAH binary
0.938
0.035
0.965
0.009
− 0.75
No health problems
0.833
0.054
0.788
0.020
0.78
Not hospitalized
0.938
0.035
0.968
0.009
− 0.83
No operation
0.875
0.048
0.973
0.008
− 2.00
HH has money for treatment and medicine
0.865
0.057
0.793
0.023
1.17
Log (1 + Medical treatment per HH capita, 30 days)
5.891
0.420
5.780
0.156
0.25
Log (1 + Medicine bought per HH capita, 30 days)
4.754
0.233
4.867
0.083
− 0.46
Log (1 + Income)
4.050
0.634
3.899
0.206
0.23
Table 11
Selection tests for non-working females (*p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001)
Indicator
Job with VHI
Job without VHI
t st
Mean
St. err
Mean
St. err
SAH binary
0.962
0.026
0.940
0.010
0.80
No health problems
0.648
0.066
0.671
0.020
− 0.33
Not hospitalized
0.963
0.026
0.933
0.010
1.08
No operation
0.962
0.026
0.960
0.008
0.06
HH has money for treatment and medicine
0.707
0.072
0.756
0.020
− 0.65
Log (1 + Medical treatment per HH capita, 30 days)
6.128
0.476
6.210
0.144
− 0.16
Log (1 + Medicine bought per HH capita, 30 days)
5.127
0.209
5.121
0.062
0.03
Log (1 + Income)
4.305
0.578
4.310
0.165
− 0.01
Table 12
\(\beta_{1}\), \(\beta_{2}\), and their ratios in FE models estimated on sample of respondents who were voluntary insured for at least a year in 2000–2017
 
Doctor
Smoke
Smoke_n
Drink
Drink_n
Sport
bmi_dec
sah
Male and female
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.211*** (0.034)
− 0.012 (0.009)
0.225 (0.359)
0.062*** (0.013)
0.025 (0.041)
0.059 (0.041)
− 0.112* (0.048)
− 0.019 (0.017)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.139*** (0.016)
− 0.001 (0.004)
0.321* (0.149)
0.023*** (0.006)
0.045* (0.018)
0.042* (0.018)
0.061** (0.022)
− 0.006 (0.008)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.660** (0.131)
0.078** (0.346)
1.427 (2.367)
0.366*** (0.125)
1.819 (3.062)
0.715 (0.590)
− 0.543 (0.307)
0.331 (0.509)
 Observations
27,379
32,649
11,342
24,874
20,707
30,265
32,675
32,531
 Respondents
4150
4352
1990
4021
3772
4329
4353
4353
Age 17–35
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.288*** (0.055)
− 0.034* (0.015)
0.100 (0.517)
0.069** (0.021)
0.028 (0.065)
0.006 (0.069)
− 0.172* (0.082)
− 0.042 (0.027)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.172*** (0.025)
− 0.005 (0.007)
0.115 (0.209)
0.024* (0.010)
0.038 (0.029)
0.047 (0.031)
0.093* (0.038)
− 0.015 (0.013)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.596** (0.144)
0.137*** (0.220)
1.143 (6.236)
0.345*** (0.176)
1.369 (3.353)
7.886 (91.976)
− 0.543 (0.342)
0.358 (0.381)
 Observations
11,107
13,602
5057
9901
8801
12,556
13,616
13,557
 Respondents
2226
2439
1198
2096
2077
2424
2440
2440
Age 36–72
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.172*** (0.045)
0.001 (0.010)
0.130 (0.497)
0.053** (0.018)
0.029 (0.054)
0.092 (0.051)
− 0.028 (0.058)
− 0.009 (0.022)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.104*** (0.021)
0.000 (0.005)
0.386 (0.215)
0.018* (0.008)
0.053* (0.025)
0.046* (0.023)
0.022 (0.027)
− 0.004 (0.010)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.607* (0.200)
0.370 (9.937)
2.960 (11.397)
0.341*** (0.185)
1.853 (3.587)
0.495 (0.373)
− 0.790 (1.888)
0.422 (1.470)
 Observations
16,272
19,047
6285
14,973
11,906
17,709
19,059
18,974
 Respondents
2625
2749
1156
2552
2346
2726
2749
2749
Male
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.104* (0.052)
− 0.012 (0.016)
0.228 (0.463)
0.055** (0.020)
0.036 (0.066)
0.063 (0.066)
− 0.104 (0.078)
− 0.019 (0.027)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.149*** (0.021)
0.000 (0.006)
0.356 (0.182)
0.006 (0.008)
0.058* (0.026)
0.036 (0.026)
0.058 (0.032)
− 0.002 (0.011)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
1.435 (0.746)
− 0.003 (0.521)
1.559 (3.247)
0.106*** (0.146)
1.616 (3.037)
0.564 (0.724)
− 0.557 (0.522)
0.097 (0.598)
 Observations
13,220
15,764
8333
11,988
11,288
14,588
15,773
15,694
 Respondents
2094
2195
1410
2029
1990
2182
2196
2196
Female
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.281*** (0.046)
− 0.010 (0.010)
0.158 (0.514)
0.066*** (0.018)
0.016 (0.050)
0.057 (0.052)
− 0.120* (0.061)
− 0.019 (0.022)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.130*** (0.024)
− 0.003 (0.005)
0.099 (0.246)
0.039*** (0.009)
0.026 (0.025)
0.049 (0.026)
0.065* (0.031)
− 0.010 (0.011)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.462*** (0.113)
0.295 (0.553)
0.625 (2.573)
0.592 (0.216)
1.658 (5.481)
0.872 (0.922)
− 0.543 (0.375)
0.551 (0.859)
 Observations
14,159
16,885
3009
12,886
9419
15,677
16,902
16,837
 Respondents
2056
2157
580
1992
1782
2147
2157
2157
Low education
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.160** (0.051)
− 0.012 (0.013)
0.325 (0.485)
0.065*** (0.020)
0.028 (0.061)
0.091 (0.056)
− 0.203** (0.070)
− 0.062* (0.024)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.114*** (0.022)
0.002 (0.006)
0.449* (0.194)
0.025** (0.008)
0.049 (0.026)
0.059* (0.024)
0.037 (0.031)
0.004 (0.011)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.711 (0.262)
− 0.127 (0.478)
1.384 (2.149)
0.393*** (0.175)
1.746 (3.952)
0.644 (0.480)
− 0.184*** (0.167)
− 0.059*** (0.176)
 Observations
15,772
19,319
7562
14,138
11,883
17,886
19,334
19,243
 Respondents
2585
2825
1381
2452
2339
2811
2826
2826
High education
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.246*** (0.048)
− 0.011 (0.012)
− 0.017 (0.523)
0.054** (0.018)
0.022 (0.055)
0.026 (0.061)
− 0.016 (0.064)
0.021 (0.024)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.151*** (0.023)
− 0.002 (0.006)
0.223 (0.238)
0.022* (0.009)
0.057* (0.026)
0.019 (0.029)
0.069* (0.031)
− 0.023* (0.011)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.614* (0.151)
0.200 (0.569)
− 12.846 (387.470)
0.403** (0.212)
2.638 (6.805)
0.701 (1.958)
− 4.283 (17.233)
− 1.082 (1.323)
 Observations
11,607
13,330
3780
10,736
8824
12,379
13,341
13,288
 Respondents
1971
2038
764
1922
1804
2021
2039
2039
Moscow/St Petersburg
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.359*** (0.094)
0.033 (0.025)
0.346 (1.051)
0.026 (0.037)
0.105 (0.110)
0.221* (0.107)
0.160 (0.121)
0.071 (0.046)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.218*** (0.038)
0.003 (0.009)
0.393 (0.325)
0.017 (0.014)
0.091* (0.043)
0.118** (0.040)
0.045 (0.045)
− 0.008 (0.017)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.608* (0.193)
0.091** (0.299)
1.136 (3.604)
0.666 (1.087)
0.870 (1.008)
0.534 + (0.318)
0.281* (0.359)
− 0.116*** (0.251)
 Observations
4292
5194
1926
3830
3461
4785
5196
5172
 Respondents
790
865
418
740
777
861
866
866
Other regions
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.180*** (0.037)
− 0.019* (0.009)
0.228 (0.383)
0.068*** (0.014)
0.010 (0.044)
0.031 (0.045)
− 0.151** (0.053)
− 0.033 (0.018)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.120*** (0.017)
− 0.002 (0.005)
0.321 (0.168)
0.024*** (0.007)
0.032 (0.020)
0.026 (0.021)
0.065* (0.025)
− 0.006 (0.009)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.665* (0.166)
0.107*** (0.248)
1.407 (2.460)
0.355*** (0.123)
3.326 (15.273)
0.837 (1.381)
− 0.430* (0.225)
0.185** (0.283)
 Observations
23,087
27,455
9416
21,044
17,246
25,480
27,479
27,359
 Respondents
3360
3487
1572
3281
2995
3468
3487
3487
Standard errors in parentheses. The significance tests reported for the \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\) rows tests that the absolute value of the ratio equals one
*p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001
Table 13
Average marginal effects of \(self\) and \(ent\) conditional on zero individual fixed effects, \(\alpha_{i}\), and their ratios in FE logit models
 
Smoke
Drink
Male and female
 Self
− 0.046 (0.033)
0.209*** (0.041)
 Ent
− 0.001 (0.014)
0.054*** (0.016)
 Self/ent
0.018** (0.313)
0.259*** (0.090)
 Observations
42,299
67,017
 Respondents
5231
9781
Age 17–35
 Self
− 0.089* (0.040)
0.224*** (0.064)
 Ent
− 0.012 (0.018)
0.049* (0.024)
 Self/ent
0.131*** (0.207)
0.219*** (0.123)
 Observations
19,419
23,804
 Respondents
2924
4124
Age 36–72
 Self
0.013 (0.054)
0.184*** (0.056)
 Ent
0.001 (0.021)
0.045* (0.021)
 Self/ent
0.091 (1.723)
0.244*** (0.126)
 Observations
19,459
40,126
 Respondents
2433
5837
Male
Self
− 0.056 (0.046)
0.206** (0.072)
Ent
0.001 (0.019)
0.010 (0.024)
Self/ent
− 0.010** (0.339)
0.050*** (0.116)
Observations
25,400
24,160
Respondents
3131
3616
Female
 Self
− 0.043 (0.043)
0.210*** (0.050)
 Ent
− 0.013 (0.020)
0.084*** (0.020)
 Self/ent
0.306 (0.579)
0.398*** (0.134)
 Observations
16,899
42,857
 Respondents
2100
6165
Low education
 Self
− 0.054 (0.045)
0.231*** (0.061)
 Ent
0.003 (0.019)
0.068** (0.021)
 Self/ent
− 0.055** (0.352)
0.293*** (0.119)
 Observations
30,027
45,791
 Respondents
3859
6919
High education
 Self
− 0.052 (0.054)
0.156** (0.051)
 Ent
− 0.001 (0.025)
0.043* (0.021)
 Self/ent
0.017* (0.489)
0.279*** (0.162)
 Observations
10,465
19,365
 Respondents
1396
2946
Moscow/St Petersburg
 Self
0.113 (0.099)
0.125 (0.114)
 Ent
0.014 (0.034)
0.043 (0.035)
 Self/ent
0.123** (0.325)
0.345 (0.414)
 Observations
4914
7343
 Respondents
719
1217
Other regions
 Self
− 0.071* (0.036)
0.218*** (0.043)
 Ent
− 0.005 (0.016)
0.058*** (0.017)
 Self/ent
0.064*** (0.228)
0.265*** (0.095)
 Observations
37,385
59,674
 Respondents
4512
8564
Standard errors in parentheses. The significance tests reported for the \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\) rows tests that the marginal effects ratio equals one. *p  < 0.05, **p  <  0.01, ***p  < 0.001
Table 14
Average marginal effects of \(self\) and \(ent\) conditional on zero individual fixed effects, \(\alpha_{i}\), and their ratios in BUC models
 
Doctor
Drink_n
Sport
bmi_dec
sah
Male and female
 Self
0.128*** (0.022)
0.014 (0.023)
0.032 (0.024)
− 0.047* (0.022)
− 0.021 (0.021)
 Ent
0.085*** (0.010)
0.024* (0.010)
0.024* (0.011)
0.025* (0.010)
− 0.007 (0.009)
 Self/ent
0.661* (0.134)
1.653 (2.693)
0.737 (0.650)
− 0.543 (0.333)
0.323 (0.552)
 Blown up observations
282,274
188,461
280,435
559,261
175,824
 Respondents
20,727
15,344
14,825
23,472
18,304
Age 17–35
 Self
0.157*** (0.032)
0.015 (0.031)
0.003 (0.028)
− 0.064 (0.033)
− 0.046 (0.032)
 Ent
0.097*** (0.014)
0.019 (0.013)
0.026* (0.013)
0.034* (0.015)
− 0.017 (0.014)
 Self/ent
0.618* (0.156)
1.276 (2.758)
7.541 (61.655)
− 0.541 (0.371)
0.366 (0.414)
 Blown up observations
102,759
68,481
112,747
222,011
61,803
 Respondents
9460
7257
7863
11,294
8400
Age 36–72
 Self
0.068** (0.021)
0.016 (0.032)
0.059 (0.035)
− 0.012 (0.026)
− 0.010 (0.021)
 Ent
0.041*** (0.011)
0.027 (0.014)
0.028 (0.015)
0.009 (0.012)
− 0.004 (0.010)
 Self/ent
0.608* (0.191)
1.675 (3.495)
0.467 (0.371)
− 0.754 (1.830)
0.386 (1.227)
 Blown up observations
166,320
108,528
149,180
302,140
104,057
 Respondents
12,431
8998
7610
13,895
10,872
Male
 Self
0.071* (0.030)
0.018 (0.033)
0.032 (0.034)
− 0.042 (0.033)
− 0.008 (0.030)
 Ent
0.095*** (0.013)
0.028* (0.012)
0.020 (0.013)
0.028* (0.014)
− 0.005 (0.012)
 Self/ent
1.337 (0.585)
1.540 (2.907)
0.614 (0.751)
− 0.651 (0.610)
0.600 (2.688)
 Blown up observations
109,063
108,522
121,800
255,134
77,927
 Respondents
8949
8145
6673
10,685
8438
Female
 Self
0.161*** (0.029)
0.009 (0.031)
0.030 (0.033)
− 0.049 (0.029)
− 0.031 (0.028)
 Ent
0.074*** (0.014)
0.015 (0.016)
0.026 (0.017)
0.023 (0.015)
− 0.009 (0.014)
 Self/ent
0.458*** (0.120)
1.661 (5.803)
0.878 (1.144)
− 0.462 (0.401)
0.288 (0.522)
 Blown up observations
173,211
79,939
158,635
304,127
97,897
 Respondents
11,778
7199
8152
12,787
9866
Low education
 Self
0.098** (0.031)
0.013 (0.032)
0.055 (0.038)
− 0.084** (0.031)
− 0.066* (0.030)
 Ent
0.071*** (0.014)
0.023 (0.012)
0.042* (0.017)
0.019 (0.014)
0.005 (0.013)
 Self/ent
0.727 (0.263)
1.817 (4.745)
0.761 (0.609)
− 0.222*** (0.187)
− 0.079*** (0.193)
 Blown up observations
191,061
129,917
173,897
397,562
123,655
 Respondents
14,774
10,903
9991
17,389
13,414
High education
 Self
0.147*** (0.030)
0.017 (0.035)
0.017 (0.037)
− 0.004 (0.031)
0.023 (0.029)
 Ent
0.089*** (0.014)
0.036* (0.016)
0.006 (0.017)
0.028 (0.015)
− 0.027 (0.014)
 Self/ent
0.604* (0.156)
2.124 (4.420)
0.362 (1.277)
− 6.681 (49.719)
− 1.194 (1.614)
 Blown up observations
84,041
53,687
95,363
142,101
47,640
 Respondents
6531
4745
5326
6961
5327
Moscow/St Petersburg
 Self
0.196** (0.060)
0.066 (0.056)
0.097 (0.057)
0.079 (0.054)
0.095 (0.060)
 Ent
0.115*** (0.022)
0.049* (0.023)
0.058** (0.022)
0.013 (0.022)
− 0.006 (0.021)
 Self/ent
0.586 (0.218)
0.739 (0.714)
0.604 (0.430)
0.159** (0.304)
− 0.062*** (0.226)
 Blown up observations
31,469
22,071
33,507
55,097
18,542
 Respondents
2588
2083
2212
3033
2345
Other regions
 Self
0.114*** (0.023)
0.005 (0.025)
0.019 (0.027)
− 0.063** (0.023)
− 0.037 (0.022)
 Ent
0.076*** (0.011)
0.017 (0.010)
0.015 (0.012)
0.028* (0.011)
− 0.007 (0.010)
 Self/ent
0.668* (0.162)
3.446 (17.823)
0.773 (1.270)
− 0.439* (0.243)
0.184** (0.293)
 Blown up observations
250,805
166,390
246,928
504,164
157,282
 Respondents
18,139
13,261
12,613
20,439
15,959
Standard errors in parentheses. The significance tests reported for the \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\) rows tests that the marginal effects ratio equals one
*p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001
Table 15
Two-way tabulation of self-purchased and workplace provided VHI
   
Ent
Total
0
1
Doctor
Self
0
153,188
5748
158,936
1
738
129
867
Total
153,926
5877
159,803
Smoke
Self
0
184,578
6471
191,049
1
886
144
1,030
Total
185,464
6615
192,079
Smoke_n
Self
0
63,030
2403
65,433
1
263
48
311
Total
63,293
2451
65,744
Drink
Self
0
140,368
5428
145,796
1
661
121
782
Total
141,029
5549
146,578
Drink_n
Self
0
100,112
4675
104,787
1
596
113
709
Total
100,708
4788
105,496
Sport
Self
0
172,912
5878
178,790
1
763
128
891
Total
173,675
6006
179,681
bmi_dec
Self
0
184,689
6473
191,162
1
887
144
1031
Total
185,576
6617
192,193
sah
Self
0
183,776
6452
190,228
1
883
144
1027
Total
184,659
6596
191,255
Table 16
\(\beta_{1}\) and \(\beta_{2}\) estimates and their ratios in FE models without years when respondent has both self-purchased and workplace provided VHI
 
Doctor
Smoke
Smoke_n
Drink
Drink_n
Sport
bmi_dec
sah
Male and female
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.245*** (0.036)
− 0.016 (0.009)
0.472 (0.391)
0.077*** (0.015)
− 0.000 (0.044)
0.075 (0.041)
− 0.140** (0.052)
− 0.016 (0.018)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.148*** (0.015)
− 0.001 (0.004)
0.417** (0.150)
0.024*** (0.006)
0.041* (0.018)
0.049** (0.017)
0.055* (0.022)
− 0.005 (0.008)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.604*** (0.108)
0.064*** (0.233)
0.885 (0.785)
0.317*** (0.102)
− 176.386 (3.4e+04)
0.649 (0.412)
− 0.395** (0.222)
0.306 (0.594)
 Observations
159,674
191,935
65,696
146,457
105,383
179,553
192,049
191,111
 Respondents
32,480
35,962
15,245
30,928
26,680
35,539
35,966
35,921
Age 17–35
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.331*** (0.058)
− 0.037* (0.015)
0.314 (0.569)
0.081*** (0.024)
0.045 (0.069)
0.032 (0.070)
− 0.214* (0.090)
− 0.035 (0.029)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.182*** (0.025)
− 0.004 (0.007)
0.188 (0.212)
0.026* (0.010)
0.042 (0.028)
0.067* (0.029)
0.084* (0.039)
− 0.014 (0.012)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.550*** (0.120)
0.120*** (0.187)
0.597 (1.249)
0.316*** (0.151)
0.950 (1.580)
2.103 (4.656)
− 0.391* (0.250)
0.394 (0.471)
 Observations
63,201
76,149
29,057
57,619
43,697
71,019
76,219
75,903
 Respondents
16,537
18,643
8632
15,519
13,703
18,363
18,647
18,625
Age 36–72
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.200*** (0.048)
− 0.002 (0.010)
0.437 (0.540)
0.070*** (0.020)
− 0.035 (0.059)
0.113* (0.051)
− 0.048 (0.064)
− 0.006 (0.024)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.116*** (0.020)
0.001 (0.004)
0.489* (0.217)
0.019* (0.008)
0.040 (0.025)
0.051* (0.021)
0.022 (0.027)
− 0.003 (0.010)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.582* (0.170)
− 0.310 (3.011)
1.118 (1.446)
0.275*** (0.142)
− 1.124 (2.037)
0.454* (0.274)
− 0.458 (0.845)
0.480 (2.570)
 Observations
96,473
115,786
36,639
88,838
61,686
108,534
115,830
115,208
 Respondents
19,076
21,108
8297
18,248
15,641
20,915
21,108
21,081
Male
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.161** (0.055)
− 0.023 (0.016)
0.515 (0.509)
0.065** (0.023)
0.008 (0.073)
0.063 (0.067)
− 0.155 (0.088)
− 0.025 (0.030)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.161*** (0.020)
0.000 (0.006)
0.466* (0.184)
0.007 (0.008)
0.056* (0.026)
0.044 (0.024)
0.061 (0.033)
− 0.004 (0.011)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
1.005 (0.363)
– 0.018*** (0.268)
0.906 (0.948)
0.106*** (0.127)
7.164 (66.558)
0.704 (0.821)
− 0.393 (0.317)
0.179 (0.496)
 Observations
68,875
83,208
47,531
63,331
54,031
77,828
83,245
82,810
 Respondents
14,766
16,477
10,694
14,009
13,315
16,281
16,479
16,458
Female
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.297*** (0.048)
− 0.012 (0.009)
0.317 (0.547)
0.083*** (0.020)
− 0.007 (0.053)
0.080 (0.052)
− 0.131* (0.064)
− 0.011 (0.023)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.135*** (0.023)
− 0.004 (0.004)
0.177 (0.244)
0.042*** (0.010)
0.020 (0.025)
0.053* (0.024)
0.050 (0.031)
− 0.005 (0.011)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.455*** (0.105)
0.300 (0.434)
0.559 (1.209)
0.502** (0.166)
− 2.662 (19.534)
0.658 (0.507)
− 0.381* (0.303)
0.494 (1.418)
 Observations
90,799
108,727
18,165
83,126
51,352
101,725
108,804
108,301
 Respondents
17,714
19,485
4551
16,919
13,365
19,258
19,487
19,463
Low education
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.217*** (0.052)
− 0.017 (0.012)
0.465 (0.517)
0.072** (0.022)
− 0.038 (0.065)
0.095 (0.054)
− 0.245*** (0.074)
− 0.068** (0.025)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.125*** (0.022)
0.001 (0.005)
0.565** (0.191)
0.027** (0.009)
0.038 (0.026)
0.065** (0.022)
0.037 (0.032)
0.004 (0.011)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.578* (0.167)
− 0.051** (0.307)
1.213 (1.391)
0.372*** (0.165)
− 0.993 (1.854)
0.681 (0.443)
− 0.152*** (0.139)
− 0.059*** (0.162)
 Observations
111,984
136,962
51,795
102,039
73,230
128,098
137,050
136,367
 Respondents
24,199
27,310
12,270
22,811
19,598
26,960
27,314
27,278
High education
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.261*** (0.053)
− 0.014 (0.012)
0.380 (0.584)
0.076*** (0.021)
0.040 (0.060)
0.041 (0.066)
− 0.021 (0.070)
0.035 (0.027)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.155*** (0.023)
− 0.002 (0.005)
0.332 (0.245)
0.025** (0.009)
0.063* (0.026)
0.020 (0.028)
0.066* (0.030)
− 0.020 (0.012)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.592** (0.143)
0.168* (0.404)
0.872 (1.459)
0.335*** (0.149)
1.603 (2.472)
0.490 (1.029)
− 3.163 (10.784)
− 0.575 (0.557)
 Observations
47,690
54,973
13,901
44,418
32,153
51,455
54,999
54,744
 Respondents
10,040
10,758
3496
9696
8405
10,628
10,759
10,749
Moscow/St Petersburg
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.439*** (0.107)
0.023 (0.027)
1.352 (1.271)
0.014 (0.045)
0.120 (0.131)
0.284* (0.122)
0.089 (0.147)
0.071 (0.055)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.226*** (0.037)
0.003 (0.009)
0.407 (0.325)
0.015 (0.015)
0.095* (0.044)
0.122** (0.040)
0.019 (0.048)
− 0.005 (0.018)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.515** (0.148)
0.145* (0.410)
0.301 (0.363)
1.103 (3.752)
0.794 (0.915)
0.431* (0.228)
0.216 (0.631)
− 0.065*** (0.256)
 Observations
18,054
22,011
8842
16,191
12,716
20,372
22,019
21,896
 Respondents
4454
5150
2386
4043
3935
5066
5152
5143
Other regions
 \(\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.213*** (0.039)
− 0.021* (0.009)
0.404 (0.411)
0.086*** (0.016)
− 0.016 (0.047)
0.045 (0.043)
− 0.171** (0.056)
− 0.027 (0.019)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2}\)
0.129*** (0.017)
− 0.002 (0.004)
0.434* (0.169)
0.026*** (0.007)
0.027 (0.020)
0.031 (0.019)
0.064* (0.025)
− 0.004 (0.009)
 \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\)
0.606** (0.133)
0.093*** (0.201)
1.073 (1.149)
0.309*** (0.098)
− 1.667 (5.140)
0.704 (0.786)
− 0.376** (0.196)
0.166* (0.344)
 Observations
141,620
169,924
56,854
130,266
92,667
159,181
170,030
169,215
 Respondents
28,026
30,812
12,859
26,885
22,745
30,473
30,814
30,778
Standard errors in parentheses. The significance tests reported for the \(\hat{\beta }_{2} /\hat{\beta }_{1}\) rows tests that the absolute value of the ratio equals one
*p  < 0.05, **p  < 0.01, ***p  < 0.001
Table 17
Number of respondents with self-purchased and workplace provided VHI in Table 15 who answered yes to the question of whether others also paid for their insurance
 
Self
Ent
Doctor
5
18
Smoke
6
21
Smoke_n
1
6
Drink
4
14
Drink_n
6
17
Sport
7
21
bmi_dec
7
21
sah
7
21
Fußnoten
1
In fact, there is technically a fourth option as, particularly in the regions, enterprises who cannot enter the corporate VHI sector choose to finance their own medical facilities or send their employees to enterprise owned health resorts or to commission generalised preventative treatment for staff.
 
2
The RLMS-HSE is a survey conducted by Higher School of Economics and ZAO Demoscope together with Carolina Population Center, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill and the Institute of Sociology RAS (details at http://​www.​cpc.​unc.​edu/​projects/​rlms(English) and http://​www.​hse.​ru/​org/​hse/​rlms (Russian).
 
3
Although the official retirement age in Russia remains 55 for women and 60 for men, in the period covered by our data, many Russians continue to work in one or more jobs beyond this official retirement age. We therefore follow the Russian Statistical Agency (ROSSTAT) in identifying 72 as the cut off age for the economically active population.
 
4
We exclude from our analysis the small number of respondents who report ‘other’ as the source of finance for their VHI and concentrate on the distinction between enterprise funded, self-funded and no VHI.
 
6
Taking into account multiple comparisons and the large sample size, there are just two statistically significant results with reliable p values: working males who have not been hospitalised in the last year are more likely to have moved into VHI employment, and working females increase their income by moving into VHI employment. This is consistent with no adverse selection.
 
Literatur
1.
Zurück zum Zitat Newhouse, J.: Free for All: Lessons from the Health Insurance Experiment and the Insurance Experiment Group. Harvard University Press, Cambridge (1993) Newhouse, J.: Free for All: Lessons from the Health Insurance Experiment and the Insurance Experiment Group. Harvard University Press, Cambridge (1993)
2.
Zurück zum Zitat Finkelstein, A., Taubman, S., Wright, B., Bernstein, M., Gruber, J., Newhouse, J., Allen, H., Baicker, K.: Oregon Health Study Group: The Oregon Health Insurance Experiment: evidence from the first year. Q. J. Econ. 127(3), 1057–1106 (2012)PubMedPubMedCentral Finkelstein, A., Taubman, S., Wright, B., Bernstein, M., Gruber, J., Newhouse, J., Allen, H., Baicker, K.: Oregon Health Study Group: The Oregon Health Insurance Experiment: evidence from the first year. Q. J. Econ. 127(3), 1057–1106 (2012)PubMedPubMedCentral
3.
Zurück zum Zitat Winkelmann, R., Staub, K.E., Baetschmann, G.: Consistent estimation of the fixed effects ordered logit model. J. R. Stat. Soc. Ser. A (Stat. Soc.) 178(3), 685–703 (2015) Winkelmann, R., Staub, K.E., Baetschmann, G.: Consistent estimation of the fixed effects ordered logit model. J. R. Stat. Soc. Ser. A (Stat. Soc.) 178(3), 685–703 (2015)
4.
Zurück zum Zitat Arrow, K.: Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care. Am Econ Rev 53, 345 (1963) Arrow, K.: Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care. Am Econ Rev 53, 345 (1963)
5.
Zurück zum Zitat Ehrlich, I., Becker, G.: Market insurance, self-insurance and self-protection. J. Polit. Econ. 80(4), 623–648 (1972) Ehrlich, I., Becker, G.: Market insurance, self-insurance and self-protection. J. Polit. Econ. 80(4), 623–648 (1972)
6.
Zurück zum Zitat Kenkel, D.: Prevention. In: Culyer, A.J., Newhouse, J.P. (eds.) Handbook of Health Economics, vol. 1, pp. 1675–1720. Elsevier BV, Amsterdam (2000) Kenkel, D.: Prevention. In: Culyer, A.J., Newhouse, J.P. (eds.) Handbook of Health Economics, vol. 1, pp. 1675–1720. Elsevier BV, Amsterdam (2000)
7.
Zurück zum Zitat Pauly, M.: The economics of moral hazard: comment. Am. Econ. Rev. 58(3), 531–537 (1968) Pauly, M.: The economics of moral hazard: comment. Am. Econ. Rev. 58(3), 531–537 (1968)
8.
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman, M.: On the concept of health capital and demand for health. J. Polit. Econ. 80, 223–255 (1972) Grossman, M.: On the concept of health capital and demand for health. J. Polit. Econ. 80, 223–255 (1972)
9.
Zurück zum Zitat Pauly, M.V., Blavin, F.E.: Moral hazard in insurance, value-based cost sharing, and the benefits of blissful ignorance. J. Health Econ. 27(6), 1407–1417 (2008)PubMed Pauly, M.V., Blavin, F.E.: Moral hazard in insurance, value-based cost sharing, and the benefits of blissful ignorance. J. Health Econ. 27(6), 1407–1417 (2008)PubMed
10.
Zurück zum Zitat Akerlof, G.: The market for ‘lemons’: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Q. J. Econ. 84, 488–500 (1970) Akerlof, G.: The market for ‘lemons’: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Q. J. Econ. 84, 488–500 (1970)
11.
Zurück zum Zitat Rothschild, M., Stiglitz, J.: Equilibrium in competitive insurance markets: an essay on the economics of imperfect information. Q. J. Econ. 90, 630–649 (1976) Rothschild, M., Stiglitz, J.: Equilibrium in competitive insurance markets: an essay on the economics of imperfect information. Q. J. Econ. 90, 630–649 (1976)
12.
Zurück zum Zitat Chiappori, P.-A., Salanie, B.: Testing for asymmetric information in insurance markets. J. Polit. Econ. 108(1), 56–78 (2000) Chiappori, P.-A., Salanie, B.: Testing for asymmetric information in insurance markets. J. Polit. Econ. 108(1), 56–78 (2000)
13.
Zurück zum Zitat Cutler, D.M., Zeckhauser, R.J.: The anatomy of health insurance. In: Culyer, A.J., Newhouse, J.P. (eds.) Handbook of Health Economics, vol. 1, pp. 563–643. Elsevier, Amsterdam (2000) Cutler, D.M., Zeckhauser, R.J.: The anatomy of health insurance. In: Culyer, A.J., Newhouse, J.P. (eds.) Handbook of Health Economics, vol. 1, pp. 563–643. Elsevier, Amsterdam (2000)
14.
Zurück zum Zitat Manning, W.G., Newhouse, J.P., Duan, N., Keeler, E.B., Leibowitz, A.: Health insurance and the demand for medical care: evidence from a randomized experiment. Am. Econ. Rev. 77(3), 251–277 (1987)PubMed Manning, W.G., Newhouse, J.P., Duan, N., Keeler, E.B., Leibowitz, A.: Health insurance and the demand for medical care: evidence from a randomized experiment. Am. Econ. Rev. 77(3), 251–277 (1987)PubMed
15.
Zurück zum Zitat Einav, L., Finkelstein, A.: Moral hazard in health insurance: what we know and how we know it. In: NBER Working Paper. No. 24055. (2017) Einav, L., Finkelstein, A.: Moral hazard in health insurance: what we know and how we know it. In: NBER Working Paper. No. 24055. (2017)
16.
Zurück zum Zitat Akosa Antwi, Y., Asako, S.M., Simon, K.: Access to health insurance and the use of inpatient medical care: evidence from the affordable care act young adult mandate. In: National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper #20202. (2014) Akosa Antwi, Y., Asako, S.M., Simon, K.: Access to health insurance and the use of inpatient medical care: evidence from the affordable care act young adult mandate. In: National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper #20202. (2014)
17.
Zurück zum Zitat Bajari, P., Dalton, C., Hong, H., Khwaja, A.: Moral hazard, adverse selection and health expenditures: a semiparametric analysis. RAND J. Econ. 45, 747–763 (2014) Bajari, P., Dalton, C., Hong, H., Khwaja, A.: Moral hazard, adverse selection and health expenditures: a semiparametric analysis. RAND J. Econ. 45, 747–763 (2014)
18.
Zurück zum Zitat Card, D., Dobkin, C., Maestas, N.: The impact of nearly universal insurance coverage on health care utilization: evidence from Medicare. Ame. Econ. Rev. 98, 2242–2258 (2008) Card, D., Dobkin, C., Maestas, N.: The impact of nearly universal insurance coverage on health care utilization: evidence from Medicare. Ame. Econ. Rev. 98, 2242–2258 (2008)
19.
Zurück zum Zitat Cardon, J.H., Hendel, I.: Asymmetric information in health insurance: evidence from the national medical expenditure survey. RAND J. Econ. 32(3), 408–427 (2001)PubMed Cardon, J.H., Hendel, I.: Asymmetric information in health insurance: evidence from the national medical expenditure survey. RAND J. Econ. 32(3), 408–427 (2001)PubMed
20.
Zurück zum Zitat Currie, J., Gruber, J.: Health insurance eligibility, utilization of medical care, and child health. Q. J. Econ. 111, 431–466 (1996) Currie, J., Gruber, J.: Health insurance eligibility, utilization of medical care, and child health. Q. J. Econ. 111, 431–466 (1996)
21.
Zurück zum Zitat Dafny, L., Gruber, J.: Public insurance and child hospitalizations: access and efficiency effects. J. Public Econ. 89, 109–129 (2005) Dafny, L., Gruber, J.: Public insurance and child hospitalizations: access and efficiency effects. J. Public Econ. 89, 109–129 (2005)
22.
Zurück zum Zitat Keane, M.P., Stavrunova, O.: Adverse selection, moral hazard and the demand for Medigap insurance. J. Econ. 190, 62–78 (2016) Keane, M.P., Stavrunova, O.: Adverse selection, moral hazard and the demand for Medigap insurance. J. Econ. 190, 62–78 (2016)
23.
Zurück zum Zitat Taubman, S.L., Allen, H.L., Wright, B.J., Baicker, K., Finkelstein, A.N.: Medicaid increases emergency-department use: evidence from Oregon’s health insurance experiment. Science 343, 263–268 (2014)PubMedPubMedCentral Taubman, S.L., Allen, H.L., Wright, B.J., Baicker, K., Finkelstein, A.N.: Medicaid increases emergency-department use: evidence from Oregon’s health insurance experiment. Science 343, 263–268 (2014)PubMedPubMedCentral
24.
Zurück zum Zitat Chiappori, P.-A., Durand, F., Geoffard, P.Y.: Moral hazard and the demand for physician services: first lessons from a French natural experiment. Eur. Econ. Rev. 42(3–5), 499–511 (1998) Chiappori, P.-A., Durand, F., Geoffard, P.Y.: Moral hazard and the demand for physician services: first lessons from a French natural experiment. Eur. Econ. Rev. 42(3–5), 499–511 (1998)
25.
Zurück zum Zitat Buchmueller, T.C., Couffinhal, A., Grignonb, M., Perronnin, M.: Access to physician services: does supplemental insurance matter? Evidence from France. Health Econ. 13, 669–687 (2004)PubMed Buchmueller, T.C., Couffinhal, A., Grignonb, M., Perronnin, M.: Access to physician services: does supplemental insurance matter? Evidence from France. Health Econ. 13, 669–687 (2004)PubMed
26.
Zurück zum Zitat Harmon, C., Nolan, B.: Health insurance and health services utilization in Ireland. Health Econ. 10(2), 135–145 (2001)PubMed Harmon, C., Nolan, B.: Health insurance and health services utilization in Ireland. Health Econ. 10(2), 135–145 (2001)PubMed
27.
Zurück zum Zitat Kiil, A., Arendt, J.N.: The effect of complementary private health insurance on the use of health care services. Int. J. Health Econ. Manag. 17(1), 1–27 (2017)PubMed Kiil, A., Arendt, J.N.: The effect of complementary private health insurance on the use of health care services. Int. J. Health Econ. Manag. 17(1), 1–27 (2017)PubMed
28.
Zurück zum Zitat Vera-Hernandez, A.M.: Duplicate coverage and demand for health care. The case of Catalonia. Health Econ. 8(7), 579–598 (1999)PubMed Vera-Hernandez, A.M.: Duplicate coverage and demand for health care. The case of Catalonia. Health Econ. 8(7), 579–598 (1999)PubMed
29.
Zurück zum Zitat Schellhorn, M.: The effect of variable health insurance deductibles on the demand for physician visits. Health Econ. 10(5), 441–456 (2001)PubMed Schellhorn, M.: The effect of variable health insurance deductibles on the demand for physician visits. Health Econ. 10(5), 441–456 (2001)PubMed
30.
Zurück zum Zitat Thönnes, S.: Ex-post moral hazard in the health insurance market: empirical evidence from German data. Eur. J. Health Econ. 20(9), 1317–1333 (2019)PubMed Thönnes, S.: Ex-post moral hazard in the health insurance market: empirical evidence from German data. Eur. J. Health Econ. 20(9), 1317–1333 (2019)PubMed
31.
Zurück zum Zitat Dave, D., Kaestner, R.: Health insurance and ex-ante moral hazard: evidence from Medicare. Int. J. Health Care Financ. Econ. 9, 367–390 (2009) Dave, D., Kaestner, R.: Health insurance and ex-ante moral hazard: evidence from Medicare. Int. J. Health Care Financ. Econ. 9, 367–390 (2009)
32.
Zurück zum Zitat Zweifel, P., Manning, W.G.: Moral hazard and consumer incentives in health care. Handb. Health Econ. 1, 409–459 (2000) Zweifel, P., Manning, W.G.: Moral hazard and consumer incentives in health care. Handb. Health Econ. 1, 409–459 (2000)
33.
Zurück zum Zitat Brook, R.H., Ware, J.E., Rogers, W.H., Keeler, E.B., Davies, A., Donald, C., Goldberg, G.A., Lohr, K., Masthay, P.C., Newhouse, J.P.: Does free care improve adults’ health? Results from a randomized controlled trial. N. Engl. J. Med. 309, 1426–1434 (1983)PubMed Brook, R.H., Ware, J.E., Rogers, W.H., Keeler, E.B., Davies, A., Donald, C., Goldberg, G.A., Lohr, K., Masthay, P.C., Newhouse, J.P.: Does free care improve adults’ health? Results from a randomized controlled trial. N. Engl. J. Med. 309, 1426–1434 (1983)PubMed
34.
Zurück zum Zitat Courtemanche, C., Zapata, D.: Does universal coverage improve health? The Massachusetts Experience. J. Policy Anal. Manag. 33, 36–69 (2014) Courtemanche, C., Zapata, D.: Does universal coverage improve health? The Massachusetts Experience. J. Policy Anal. Manag. 33, 36–69 (2014)
35.
Zurück zum Zitat Barbaresco, S., Courtemanche, C.J., Qi, Y.: Impacts of the Affordable Care Act dependent coverage provision on health-related outcomes of young adults. J. Health Econ. 40, 54–68 (2015)PubMed Barbaresco, S., Courtemanche, C.J., Qi, Y.: Impacts of the Affordable Care Act dependent coverage provision on health-related outcomes of young adults. J. Health Econ. 40, 54–68 (2015)PubMed
36.
Zurück zum Zitat Courtemanche, C., Marton, J., Ukert, B., Yelowitz, A., Zapata, D.: Early effects of the Affordable Care Act on health care access, risky health behaviors, and self-assessed health. South. Econ. J. 84(3), 660–691 (2018) Courtemanche, C., Marton, J., Ukert, B., Yelowitz, A., Zapata, D.: Early effects of the Affordable Care Act on health care access, risky health behaviors, and self-assessed health. South. Econ. J. 84(3), 660–691 (2018)
38.
Zurück zum Zitat Simon, K., Soni, A., Cawley, J.: The impact of health insurance on preventive care and health behaviors: evidence from the first 2 years of the ACA Medicaid expansions. J. Policy Anal. Manag. 36, 390–417 (2017) Simon, K., Soni, A., Cawley, J.: The impact of health insurance on preventive care and health behaviors: evidence from the first 2 years of the ACA Medicaid expansions. J. Policy Anal. Manag. 36, 390–417 (2017)
39.
Zurück zum Zitat Stanciole, A.E.: Health insurance and lifestyle choices: identifying ExAnte moral hazard in the US market. Geneva Pap. Risk Insur. Issues Pract. 33, 627–644 (2008) Stanciole, A.E.: Health insurance and lifestyle choices: identifying ExAnte moral hazard in the US market. Geneva Pap. Risk Insur. Issues Pract. 33, 627–644 (2008)
41.
Zurück zum Zitat Courbage, C., de Coulon, A.: Prevention and private health insurance in the UK. Geneva Pap. Risk Insur. Issues Pract. 29, 719–727 (2004) Courbage, C., de Coulon, A.: Prevention and private health insurance in the UK. Geneva Pap. Risk Insur. Issues Pract. 29, 719–727 (2004)
42.
Zurück zum Zitat Finkelstein, A., McKnight, R.: What did Medicare do? The initial impact of Medicare on mortality and out of pocket medical spending. J. Public Econ. 92, 1644–1669 (2008) Finkelstein, A., McKnight, R.: What did Medicare do? The initial impact of Medicare on mortality and out of pocket medical spending. J. Public Econ. 92, 1644–1669 (2008)
43.
Zurück zum Zitat Van der Wees, P.J., Zaslavsky, A.M., Ayanian, J.Z.: Improvements in health status after Massachusetts health care reform. Milbank Q. 91, 663–689 (2013)PubMedCentral Van der Wees, P.J., Zaslavsky, A.M., Ayanian, J.Z.: Improvements in health status after Massachusetts health care reform. Milbank Q. 91, 663–689 (2013)PubMedCentral
44.
Zurück zum Zitat Cardella, E., Depew, B.: The effect of health insurance coverage on the reported health of young adults. Econ. Lett. 124(3), 406–410 (2014) Cardella, E., Depew, B.: The effect of health insurance coverage on the reported health of young adults. Econ. Lett. 124(3), 406–410 (2014)
45.
Zurück zum Zitat Sun, J., Lyu, S.: Does health insurance lead to improvement of health status among Chinese Rural Adults? Evidence from the China Family Panel Studies. Int. J. Health Serv. 50(3), 350–359 (2020)PubMed Sun, J., Lyu, S.: Does health insurance lead to improvement of health status among Chinese Rural Adults? Evidence from the China Family Panel Studies. Int. J. Health Serv. 50(3), 350–359 (2020)PubMed
46.
Zurück zum Zitat Kang, C., Kawamura, A., Noguchi, H.: Benefits of knowing own health status: effects of health check-ups on health behaviours and labour participation. Appl. Econ. Lett. 5, 1–6 (2020) Kang, C., Kawamura, A., Noguchi, H.: Benefits of knowing own health status: effects of health check-ups on health behaviours and labour participation. Appl. Econ. Lett. 5, 1–6 (2020)
47.
Zurück zum Zitat Chen, G., Yan, X.: Demand for voluntary basic medical insurance in urban China: panel evidence from the Urban Resident Basic Medical Insurance scheme. Health Policy Plan. 27(8), 658–668 (2012)PubMed Chen, G., Yan, X.: Demand for voluntary basic medical insurance in urban China: panel evidence from the Urban Resident Basic Medical Insurance scheme. Health Policy Plan. 27(8), 658–668 (2012)PubMed
48.
Zurück zum Zitat Alberga, A., Holder, L., Kornas, K., Bornbaum, C., Rosella, L.: Effects of behavioural risk factors on high-cost users of healthcare: a population-based study. Can. J. Public Health 109(4), 441–450 (2018)PubMedPubMedCentral Alberga, A., Holder, L., Kornas, K., Bornbaum, C., Rosella, L.: Effects of behavioural risk factors on high-cost users of healthcare: a population-based study. Can. J. Public Health 109(4), 441–450 (2018)PubMedPubMedCentral
49.
Zurück zum Zitat Gerry, C.J., Kaneva, M., Zasimova, L.: Reforming voluntary drug insurance in Russian health care: does social solidarity matter? Health Policy 121(11), 1177–1185 (2017)PubMed Gerry, C.J., Kaneva, M., Zasimova, L.: Reforming voluntary drug insurance in Russian health care: does social solidarity matter? Health Policy 121(11), 1177–1185 (2017)PubMed
53.
Zurück zum Zitat Ettner, S.: Adverse selection, the purchase of medigap insurance by the elderly. J. Health Econ. 16(5), 543–562 (1997)PubMed Ettner, S.: Adverse selection, the purchase of medigap insurance by the elderly. J. Health Econ. 16(5), 543–562 (1997)PubMed
54.
Zurück zum Zitat Gerry, C.J., Papadopoulos, G.: Sample attrition in RLMS, 2001–2010. Lessons for longitudinal analysis and an application in health. Econ. Transit. 23, 425–458 (2015) Gerry, C.J., Papadopoulos, G.: Sample attrition in RLMS, 2001–2010. Lessons for longitudinal analysis and an application in health. Econ. Transit. 23, 425–458 (2015)
55.
Zurück zum Zitat Doiron, D., Jones, G., Savage, E.: Healthy, wealthy and insured? The role of self-assessed health in the demand for private health insurance. Health Econ. 17(3), 317–334 (2008)PubMed Doiron, D., Jones, G., Savage, E.: Healthy, wealthy and insured? The role of self-assessed health in the demand for private health insurance. Health Econ. 17(3), 317–334 (2008)PubMed
56.
Zurück zum Zitat Grunow, M., Nuscheler, R.: Public and private health insurance in Germany: the ignored risk selection problem. Health Econ. 23(6), 670–687 (2014)PubMed Grunow, M., Nuscheler, R.: Public and private health insurance in Germany: the ignored risk selection problem. Health Econ. 23(6), 670–687 (2014)PubMed
57.
Zurück zum Zitat Lancaster, T.: The incidental parameter problem since 1948. J. Econ. 95, 391–413 (2000) Lancaster, T.: The incidental parameter problem since 1948. J. Econ. 95, 391–413 (2000)
58.
Zurück zum Zitat Neyman, J., Scott, E.L.: Consistent estimation from partially consistent observations. Econometrica 16, 1–32 (1948) Neyman, J., Scott, E.L.: Consistent estimation from partially consistent observations. Econometrica 16, 1–32 (1948)
59.
Zurück zum Zitat Quirmbach, D., Gerry, C.J.: Gender, education and Russia’s tobacco epidemic: a lifecourse approach. Soc. Sci. Med. 160, 54–66 (2016)PubMed Quirmbach, D., Gerry, C.J.: Gender, education and Russia’s tobacco epidemic: a lifecourse approach. Soc. Sci. Med. 160, 54–66 (2016)PubMed
60.
Zurück zum Zitat Rezayatmand, R., Groot, W., Pavlova, M.: Smoking behaviour and health care costs coverage: a European cross-country comparison. Int. J. Health Econ. Manag. 17(4), 453–471 (2017)PubMedPubMedCentral Rezayatmand, R., Groot, W., Pavlova, M.: Smoking behaviour and health care costs coverage: a European cross-country comparison. Int. J. Health Econ. Manag. 17(4), 453–471 (2017)PubMedPubMedCentral
61.
Zurück zum Zitat Qin, X., Lu, T.: Does health insurance lead to ex ante moral hazard? Evidence from China’s New Rural Cooperative Medical Scheme. Geneva Pap. Risk Insur. Issues Pract. 39(4), 625–650 (2014) Qin, X., Lu, T.: Does health insurance lead to ex ante moral hazard? Evidence from China’s New Rural Cooperative Medical Scheme. Geneva Pap. Risk Insur. Issues Pract. 39(4), 625–650 (2014)
Metadaten
Titel
Voluntary private health insurance, health-related behaviours and health outcomes: evidence from Russia
verfasst von
Andrey Aistov
Ekaterina Aleksandrova
Christopher J. Gerry
Publikationsdatum
23.12.2020
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
The European Journal of Health Economics / Ausgabe 2/2021
Print ISSN: 1618-7598
Elektronische ISSN: 1618-7601
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-020-01252-2

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 2/2021

The European Journal of Health Economics 2/2021 Zur Ausgabe