Skip to main content
Erschienen in: International Journal for Equity in Health 1/2017

Open Access 01.12.2017 | Research

Who pays for healthcare in Bangladesh? An analysis of progressivity in health systems financing

verfasst von: Azaher Ali Molla, Chunhuei Chi

Erschienen in: International Journal for Equity in Health | Ausgabe 1/2017

Abstract

Background

The relationship between payments towards healthcare and ability to pay is a measure of financial fairness. Analysis of progressivity is important from an equity perspective as well as for macroeconomic and political analysis of healthcare systems. Bangladesh health systems financing is characterized by high out-of-pocket payments (63.3%), which is increasing. Hence, we aimed to see who pays what part of this high out-of-pocket expenditure. To our knowledge, this was the first progressivity analysis of health systems financing in Bangladesh.

Methods

We used data from Bangladesh Household Income and Expenditure Survey, 2010. This was a cross sectional and nationally representative sample of 12,240 households consisting of 55,580 individuals. For quantification of progressivity, we adopted the ‘ability-to-pay’ principle developed by O’Donnell, van Doorslaer, Wagstaff, and Lindelow (2008). We used the Kakwani index to measure the magnitude of progressivity.

Results

Health systems financing in Bangladesh is regressive. Inequality increases due to healthcare payments. The differences between the Gini coefficient and the Kakwani index for all sources of finance are negative, which indicates regressivity, and that financing is more concentrated among the poor. Income inequality increases due to high out-of-pocket payments. The increase in income inequality caused by out-of-pocket payments is 89% due to negative vertical effect and 11% due to horizontal inequity.

Conclusions

Our findings add substantial evidence of health systems financing impact on inequitable financial burden of healthcare and income. The heavy reliance on out-of-pocket payments may affect household living standards. If the government and people of Bangladesh are concerned about equitable financing burden, our study suggests that Bangladesh needs to reform the health systems financing scheme.

Background

The relationship between payments toward healthcare and ability to pay (ATP) is a common measure of equity [1]. Who pays how much share for healthcare is a question of financial fairness. The measurement of progressivity or regressivity is important not only for a wide range of equity perspective, but also for macroeconomic and political analysis of healthcare systems [2]. Inequalities exist in almost all sectors but inequalities in the health sector have more negative impacts than in other sectors [3, 4].
The issue of equity is widely acknowledged by health economists and health policy researchers to be an important policy objective in the healthcare field [58]. Its importance is recognized not only in low and middle-income countries (LMICs), but also in high-income countries (HICs). In Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries, equity appears to be a prominent issue in the continuing debate on healthcare financing and delivery [9, 10]. In the same way, there is a strong agreement among the policy makers in low-income countries that equity should feature prominently in health policy decisions [1113]. The WHO has placed health equity as the second of its thirty-eight targets within the new “Policy for Health for All”. The policy says that by the year 2020 the health gap between socioeconomic groups within countries should be reduced by at least one fourth in all member states [14].
Without a well-functioning healthcare financing system, timely access to health services cannot be achieved for the majority of the population. The system itself determines whether people can afford to use health services without any financial hardships when they need them. Thus, recognizing the importance of equitable health systems financing (HSF), the World Health Organization (WHO) committed and recommended that countries develop a financing system so that all people have access to services and do not suffer financial hardship paying for them [14]. The sixty-fourth World Health Assembly [15] urged member states to avoid significant direct payments at the point of delivery, and to include a method for prepayment of financial contributions for healthcare and services. It also urged members to devise a mechanism to pool risks among the population to avoid catastrophic healthcare expenditure and impoverishment of individuals and households.
With an area of 56,977 miles and a population of 161.03 million [16], Bangladesh is going through a demographic and epidemiologic transition [17]. The country is the eighth most populous country of the world while it is the 94th largest by area. 28.27% of the populations are below 14 years of age and 6.04% are above 65 years with a dependency ration 52.5%. The population growth rate is 1.05% (2016 est.) with a life expectancy at birth of 73.2 years. Yet food and waterborne diseases (bacterial and protozoal diarrhea, hepatitis A and E, and typhoid fever) and vector-borne diseases (dengue, malaria) are highly prevalent. The economy has grown roughly 6% per year since1996 [18].
Bangladesh HSF is characterized by increasingly high out-of-pocket (OOP) payments, and, at the same time, the absence of an active prepayment system [18]. In Bangladesh, OOP payments as percent of private expenditure on health (92.9%) is higher than India (89.2%) and Nepal (79.9%) [19]. The Bangladesh National Health Accounts [18] reports that household OOP expenditure remains the main source of HSF, increasing from 56.9% in 1997 to 63.3% in 2012 of total health expenditure (THE). The second largest financing agent is government, making up 26.0% of THE. The private firms’ share has remained at around 1.0% over the years. The share of non-government organizations (NGOs) from their own sources has ranged between 1% and 2.0% of the THE over the 1997–2012 period. Development partners contribute through NGOs or government. The rest of the expenditure through NGOs varied from 5% to 9% during the period. Household expenditure as a percentage of GDP increased from 1.6% to around 20.0% in 2010.
The health spending in Bangladesh accounted for 3.4% of gross domestic product (GDP), which is lower than the average (3.8%) in South East Asia (SEA) region, below the average of low-income countries (5.4%), lower-middle income countries (4.3%), and far below the world (8.5%) [19]. A breakdown of OOP expenditure shows that drugs and medicine constitute 65.0% of OOP spending. Other components of OOP are services of curative care (22.0%), ancillary services (9.0%), outpatient and home-based services (4.0%), and general government administration of health (less than 1.0%).
The consequences of excess OOP expending are enormous with different scenarios. Some households may not utilize formal healthcare at all due to excess OOP payments, or they may receive partial care and thus aggravate the disease condition, causing the disease to become a chronic condition. Households may sell their movable and immovable properties to manage the treatment costs, which in turn make them poorer. Due to excess health expenditures, households may need to ration their food items, and thus may become malnourished. OOP health expenditure may affect education, causing children to drop out of school. Moreover, OOP payments may mislead planners and policy makers to miscalculate poverty status.
Policy makers and planners are not fully aware of the situation due to the acute shortage of health policy research in Bangladesh. We aim to analyze progressivity to examine if inequities in health systems financing (HSF) exist. This will provide an evidence base for health planners and policy makers who want to promote equity in HSF. In addition to numerical differences, this study will employ statistical and macro-economic analysis and techniques to examine equity using Bangladesh Household Income and Expenditure Surveys [20]. This research seems to be the first of its kind to analyze of progressivity of HSF in Bangladesh using nationwide survey dataset.
We evaluated progressivity of HSF from all sources of available financing: tax, social insurance, private insurance, and OOP payments. We did not consider foreign aid, as it is not relevant because our purpose was to evaluate the distributional impact of domestic source of health systems financing on the domestic population. Assuming tax parameters have been set for foreign loan repayment, the distributional burden on the current generation of foreign debt financing will be captured through the evaluation of the tax distribution.

Data and methods

Sampling technique

We use the Bangladesh Household Income and Expenditure Survey [20] dataset conducted by Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics (BBS). This is the source of data for estimating household income, expenditure, consumption, income inequality and incidence of poverty. For this round, data collection was started on 1st February 2010 and continued up to 31st January 2011.
A two-stage stratified random sampling technique was followed in drawing the sample for this survey under the framework of Integrated Multipurpose Sampling (IMPS) design developed on the basis of the 2001 Bangladesh population and housing census. In IMPS design, the whole country was divided into 16 strata, which included six from rural, six from urban, and four from sub-municipal areas (SMAs). The design consists of 1000 primary sampling units (PSUs) throughout the country systematically drawn from the 16 strata. Out of 1000 PSUs, 640 were from rural and 360 from urban areas. Each PSU is comprised of approximately 200 households. In the first stage, 612 PSUs were drawn from 1000 PSUs. In the second stage, 20 households were randomly selected from each PSU. Thus, PSUs selected for HIES 2010 are actually a subset of PSUs of the IMPS design. The total sample size stands at 12,240 households comprising of a population of 55,580.

Methods

We used two methods to measure the progressivity of health payments: comparing the share of health payments to their share of ATP, and assessing departure from proportionality or Lorenz dominance analysis. Under the progressive system, the share of health payments are less than their ATP and the Lorenz curve dominates (lies above) the concentration curve. The opposite is true for a regressive system. Kakwani index is being used to measure the magnitude of progressivity.
We have used STATA 14.0 [21] and the Automated Development Economics and Poverty Tables (ADePT) software, version 5.0 developed by World Bank’s experts [22]. Progressivity is assessed using a direct and a less direct method. A direct method is a percentage of OOP payments for healthcare as a percentage of total household expenditure by quintile/decile groups of equivalent household expenditure. A less direct method of assessing progressivity is defined in relation to departure from proportionality. This method compares the share of health payments contributed by proportions of the populations ranked by ATP with their share of ATP. It compares the concentration curve of health payments (LH(p)) with the Lorenz curve for ATP, (L(P)). The merit of this curve is that it provides a visual representation of the distribution information. However, it does not show the distribution exactly, and it is difficult to compare this curve between the countries.
Because the Lorenz dominance analysis alone does not provide a measure of magnitude of proportionality, Kakwani index [23] is used to measure the magnitudes of progressivity/regressivity. Kakwani index is twice the area between a payment concentration curve and a Lorenz curve. It is calculated as
$$ {\pi}_k=C-G $$
(1)
Where, C is the concentration curve and G is the Gini coefficient of the ATP variable. The Gini coefficient (G) is used to measure of inequality of a distribution. The value of G varies from 0 to 1. The Gini coefficient is regarded as the gold standard in economic analysis in assessing inequality.

Key variables

The variables for this part of analysis are ability to pay (ATP) (Table 1), food consumption, non-food consumption, and amount of healthcare payments. Ability to pay for each household was calculated by adding all forms of consumption such as food consumption and non-food consumption. The amount of healthcare payments was calculated by adding all the related costs of healthcare including direct and indirect costs.
Table 1
Variables with definitions and source
Variables
Definitions
Source
Ability to pay (ATP)
Households’ yearly consumptions of food, non-food and payments towards healthcarea
HIES, 2010
Food consumption
Market price of food items consumed in one yeara
HIES, 2010
Nonfood consumption
Market price of nonfood items in one yeara
HIES, 2010
Healthcare payments
Gross of all payments towards healthcare, including direct tax, indirect tax, social insurance and private insurancea
HIES, 2010
aMeasured in Bangladesh currency Taka (Tk.). 1 Tk. = US$ 0.08

Results

The summary statistics (Table 2) show that out of 12,240 households, 11,638 households were included for analysis. The mean household size is 4.5 persons, ranging from 1 to 17 members per household. The mean households’ aggregate annual consumption is Tk. 132,510 (US$ 1656) with a range from a minimum of Tk. 15,327 (US$191.6) to a maximum of Tk. 1,843,160 (US$23,039). Nonfood consumption varies from Tk.4827 (US $60) to Tk.1,712,261 (US $21,403). There are more observations below the mean (right skewed) for both total consumption and nonfood consumption. The average contribution of tax is Tk.754, social health insurance is Tk. 142 US $9.4), and private health insurance is Tk.8 (US $0.1). Total OOP payments range from zero to Tk.1,369,000 (US $17,113) with an average of Tk.5339 (US $76) and a median of Tk.2200 (Us $28). Majority of observations are below the mean.
Table 2
Summary report of sample data (HIES), Bangladesh 2010
 
N
mean
min
max
p1
p50
p99
N_unique
Household size (person)
11,638
4.5
1.0
17.0
1.0
4.0
10.0
17
Total HH consumption (Tk.)
11,638
132,510
15,327
1,843,160
40,001
110,443
474,890
11,632
Total NF consumption (Tk.)
11,638
62,071
4827
1,712,261
10,387
42,050
354,297
10,654
Household sampling weights
11,638
2739
897.1
6882.3
897.1
2946
6882.3
16
Household tax (Tk.)
11,638
754
0.0
200,000
0.0
0.0
20,000
184
Social health insurance (Tk.)
11,638
142
0.0
120,000
0.0
0.0
3000
76
Private health insurance (Tk.)
11,638
8
0.0
50,000
0.0
0.0
0.0
9
Total OOP expenditure (Tk.)
11,638
5339
0.0
1,369,000
0.0
2200
50,000
1594
Note: p1 = 1st percentile, p50 = 50th percentile, p99 = 99th percentile

Health systems financing

The average per capita consumption for lowest, second and third quintile is lower than the total average (Tk.29,907), which indicates that majority of the population consumes less than the average (Table 3). Total consumption in the poorest quintile (Tk. 13,529) is less than half (Tk. 29,908) of the total average consumption. Direct tax appears to be born significantly higher by the richest quintile. It is also important to note that the amount of social insurance is very small. Contribution to private health insurance for each and every quintile is very negligible and insignificant. Out-of-pocket expenditure constitutes a major portion of health finance. The poorest quintile contributes Tk.842, which is half of the richest quintile (Tk.1594). Per capita consumption gross for the poorest quintile is Tk.13,529 and per capita consumption net of healthcare payments is Tk.12,635. Households in the poorest quintile consume 0.22 times the richest quintile in respect of gross consumption and 0.21 times in respect of net consumption. This clearly shows an inequity in healthcare payments between the poorest and the richest quintiles.
Table 3
Average Per Capita Health Finance by quintiles, Bangladesh 2010
 
Per capita consumption, gross (Tk.)
Household yearly tax in (Tk.)
Household yearly social health insurance in (Tk.)
Household yearly private health insurance in (Tk.)
Household yearly out-of-pocket health expenditure in (Tk.)
Total payments in (Tk.)
Per capita consumption, net of payments in (Tk.)
Lowest quintile
13,529
49
36
0.0
842
927
12,635
Standard error
62
9
9
0.0
43
47
73
2nd quintile
19,076
75
36
2
1114
1226
17,940
Standard error
34
15
8
1
89
92
63
3rd quintile
24,032
91
52
7
1378
1528
22,705
Standard error
40
15
16
5
171
173
69
4th quintile
31,690
107
63
0.0
1331
1500
30,271
Standard error
73
20
19
0.0
95
100
97
Highest quintile
61,204
192
58
0.2
1594
1844
59,424
Standard error
759
36
22
0.25
81
93
760
Total
29,907
103
49
1.8
1252
1405
28,596
standard error
238
9
7
0.93
47
49
238
Note: 1 Bangladesh Taka (Tk.) equals 0.08 dollars

Progressivity or regressivity?

Tables 4 and 5 analyze the progressivity of HSF. Table 4 gives the average consumption and financing share by quintile, with households ranked in ascending order of gross consumption. Information related to gross consumption gives an idea about income inequality; the greater of the richest quintiles, the greater the inequality.
Table 4
Household Share of Total Healthcare Financing, Bangladesh 2010
 
Per capita consumption, gross (%)
Household yearly tax (%)
Household yearly social health insurance (%)
Household yearly private health insurance (%)
Household yearly out-of-pocket health expenditure (%)
Total payments %
Per capita consumption, net of payments (%)
Quintiles of per capita consumption, gross
Lowest quintile
9.0
9.5
14.8
0.0
13.4
13.2
8.8
standard error
0.25
1.83
3.72
0.00
0.83
0.79
0.24
2
12.8
14.6
14.7
17.8
17.8
17.5
12.5
standard error
0.32
2.78
3.38
13.19
1.37
1.27
0.32
3
16.1
17.7
21.3
79.4
22.0
21.8
15.9
standard error
0.39
2.91
5.95
14.19
2.23
2.04
0.39
4
21.2
20.9
25.5
0.0
21.3
21.4
21.2
standard error
0.48
3.52
6.55
0.00
1.45
1.37
0.49
Highest quintile
40.9
37.4
23.7
2.8
25.5
26.2
41.6
standard error
0.72
4.96
7.43
3.11
1.37
1.35
0.73
Total
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
standard error
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
Gini coefficient
0.3134
     
0.3276
standard error
0.00
     
0.00
Concentration Index
 
0.2419
0.1040
−0.1208
0.1128
0.1217
 
standard error
 
0.05
0.07
0.06
0.02
0.02
 
Kakwani index
 
−0.0714
−0.2094
−0.4342
−0.2005
−0.1917
 
standard error
 
0.05
0.07
0.06
0.02
0.02
 
Table 5
Financing Budget Shares, Bangladesh 2010 (Health Financing as a Share of total gross consumption)
 
Per capita consumption, gross
Household yearly tax
Household yearly social health insurance
Household yearly private health insurance
Household yearly out-of-pocket health expenditure
Total payments
Per capita consumption, net of payments
Quintiles of per capita consumption, gross
Lowest quintile (%)
100.0
0.4
0.3
0.0
6.2
6.8
93.4
standard error
0.00
0.07
0.07
0.00
0.32
0.34
0.29
2nd quintile (%)
100.0
0.4
0.2
0.0
5.8
6.4
94.0
standard error
0.00
0.08
0.04
0.01
0.47
0.48
0.28
3rd quintile (%)
100.0
0.4
0.2
0.0
5.7
6.4
94.5
standard error
0.00
0.06
0.07
0.02
0.71
0.72
0.24
4th quintile (%)
100.0
0.3
0.2
0.0
4.2
4.7
95.5
standard error
0.00
0.06
0.06
0.00
0.30
0.31
0.20
Highest quintile (%)
100.0
0.3
0.1
0.0
2.6
3.0
97.1
standard error
0.00
0.06
0.04
0.00
0.14
0.16
0.12
Total (%)
100.0
0.3
0.2
0.0
4.2
4.7
95.6
standard error
0.00
0.03
0.02
0.00
0.16
0.17
0.09
Gini coefficient
0.3134
     
0.3276
standard error
0.00
     
0.00
Concentration Index
 
0.2419
0.1040
−0.1208
0.1128
0.1217
 
standard error
 
0.05
0.07
0.06
0.02
0.02
 
Kakwani index
 
−0.0714
−0.2094
−0.4342
−0.2005
−0.1917
 
standard error
 
0.05
0.07
0.06
0.02
0.02
 
The poorest quintile consumes, on average, 9.0% of total (gross) consumption, whereas this amounts to 41.0% for the richest quintile (Table 4). Taxes appear to be borne mostly by the upper three quintiles, 17.7, 20.9 and 37.4%. The lowest two quintiles make up 9.5 and 14.6% of the total. The financing share increases by quintile for taxes. In case of social health insurance, the fourth quintile paid the most (25.5%) followed by the highest quintile (23.7%). The lowest and the second quintile make up nearly the same percent for social insurance (14.8 and 14.7%). In both per capita gross consumption and household yearly tax, the richest quintile bears the greater share, 40.9 and 37.4% respectively, which are 4.5 and 4.0 times respectively higher than the lowest quintile. In respect of social health insurance, the poorest quintile bears a 14.8% share, whereas the richest quintile bears 23.7%.
Private health insurance is either absent, or is present only in some pocket areas. The middle class or third quintile possesses the highest share of private health insurance (79.4%). Whereas, the poorest and the fourth quintiles have no private insurance and the richest quintile has only a 2.8% share.
Financing share for household yearly OOP expenditure for the poorest quintile is approximately half (13.4%) of the richest quintile (25.5%).
The discrepancies between the share of gross consumption and OOP payments are clearly visible. The comparison between per capita gross consumption and per capita consumption net of health payments shows that share decreases among the poor (9.0 vs 8.8%) and increases among the rich (40.9 vs. 41.6%), which indicates that post-healthcare payments consumption decreases among the poor and increases among the rich. This finding supports figures for the Gini coefficient (Table 5); prepayment Gini or income inequality is less than the post-payment Gini or income inequality (0.3134 vs. 0.3276). The concentration indexes are positive except households’ private health insurance. This indicates the wealthier contribute more in absolute amount to the financing of healthcare than the poor do. For the private health insurance, the concentration index is negative which is an indication of a regressive mode of financing. The concentration index is largest for household yearly taxes (0.2419) suggesting that taxes are relatively progressive than other sources. The differences between Gini coefficient of per capita gross consumption and concentration index or Kakwani Index for all sources of healthcare financing are negative. This indicates regressivity, meaning that OOP payment is more concentrated among the poor (Table 5).
Table 5 presents health financing as a share of total gross consumption. Household OOP healthcare expenditure remains the highest share (4.2%) of all healthcare financing (tax, social insurance and private insurance). The lowest quintile spends 6.8% of their total gross consumption for healthcare compared to 3.0% for the highest quintile. This clearly shows a regressive mode of financing. The contribution of household yearly private insurance tends to zero for nearly all the quintiles. Household yearly tax and social insurance are minimal, consisting of 0.3 and 0.2% respectively.
Figure 1 shows the concentration curve for household taxes. The concentration curve of household tax lies inside the Lorenz curve at all levels of consumption. This suggests regressivity, which means that the poor pay proportionately more of their total household consumption for healthcare than the rich. In Fig. 2, both OOP expenditure and social insurance lie inside the per capita consumption gross (Lorenz curve), which indicates regressivity. Again, private insurance shows an abnormal peak just after the 20% mark of the population ranked from poorest to richest. As we discussed earlier, private insurance in Bangladesh exists in pocket areas of the country.
Finally, using the direct method, we have analyzed the overall progressivity (Fig. 3). It is the direct representation of the progressivity of health payments. It shows the health payments share by quintile. In Bangladesh, the share of health payments to household economic status, in our case consumption, decreases from the lowest quintile to the highest quintile. As is visible, the lowest quintile households pay 7.0% of their total consumption for healthcare, whereas, the highest quintile households pay about 3.3%. The bars show a sharp decreasing trend from lowest to highest quintile. We conclude that the HSF in Bangladesh is definitely regressive.

Discussions

Our findings show that health system financing in Bangladesh is regressive in nature. Payments toward healthcare are not related to ATP. Healthcare payments account for decreasing proportion of ATP. As shown by the negative Kakwani indices, health systems financing is concentrated among the poor. This indicates that inequality exists in health systems financing. Our results confirm the conclusion of previous studies conducted by Wagstaff [24, 25], Van Doorslaer [26], and Mastilica [27] that OOP payments are a regressive means of healthcare revenue collection.
A limited number of studies from low-income countries exist, but there are no studies from Bangladesh. In our analysis, the wide range of OOP expenditure indicates a large gap between households in the lowest and the highest quintiles. Household yearly social insurance is minimal with mean of Tk. 142 and median of zero indicating that although social insurance exists it is limited within a group of households. Social insurance exists in formal sectors of Bangladesh. This explains why 3rd, 4th and 5th quintiles altogether bear 70.5% (Table 4, column 4) of financing altogether. Private health insurance is nearly absent existing only in some pocket areas. Traditional insurance markets are almost entirely absent in the rural areas of Bangladesh [28]. However, the findings show that the 3rd quintile bears the most financial burden of private insurance (79.4%). The poor cannot afford private insurance and the rich do not bother at all. Some NGOs initiated certain kinds of health insurance for the rural population. Grameen Bank also started to provide a micro health insurance scheme in the late 1990s. Similarly, Gonoshasthaya Kendra (GK) initiated some kind of health insurance in limited areas for the rural poor and middle class [28].
An inequality exists in per capita gross consumption in Bangladesh. On average, the lowest quintile consumes 0.22 times the highest quintile. Contrary to this, the rate of tax borne by the lowest quintile is 0.25 times that of the highest quintile. In respect to social health insurance, the lowest quintile bears 0.62 times what the highest quintile does.
The greater share of healthcare financial burden in household is OOP payments. The poor bear 0.53 times of the rich’s burden, whereas their consumption or ATP is only 0.22 of the rich. Proportionately, the poor pay more in OOP expenditures than the rich do. This makes the payments regressive or pro-rich.
It is clearly evident that the rich consume more than their poor counterparts, but at the same time, the rich pay proportionately less in taxes, social insurance, private insurance and OOP payments. For the poor, per capita net consumption decreases (9.0 vs. 8.8%) after OOP payments, whereas for the rich per capita net consumption increases (40.9 vs. 41.6%) after OOP payments (Table 2). This is related to the transfer payments and/or redistribution of disposable income, as we have seen in decomposition of redistributive effects. These findings are concordant with the Gini coefficients we estimated; prepayment Gini is less than the post payment Gini (0.3134 vs 0.3276). The positive concentration indexes indicate that the rich pay more in absolute terms but proportionately less. The concentration index is the largest for household yearly tax, suggesting that in terms of progressivity, taxes are relatively better than all other financing sources. Similarly, the Gini coefficient of per capita gross consumption and concentration index or Kakwani index for all sources of financing are negative; this indicates regressivity.
In Bangladesh, like other low-income countries, OOP payments contribute the greatest share of revenue (63.3%). The Lorenz dominance analysis indicates that the inequality exists in all sources of health systems financing (Figs. 1 and 2). Both the graphs offer a powerful means of representing the effect of health systems financing on the distribution of household living standards. It should be noted that this kind of analysis does not consider utilization of healthcare. Progressivity should not be interpreted as the rich paying more for the same amount of healthcare, as this is most often not the case and not accounted for the measure presented here.
The overall progressivity/regressivity analysis we performed used a direct measure. The results indicate, with little ambiguity, that it is regressive, as the lower income quintiles’ share of household consumption decreases with healthcare consumption. This clearly indicates that the health systems financing in Bangladesh is regressive.
The findings, although rich with both statistical and policy significance, should be interpreted in view of several limitations. Firstly, estimates of OOP payments from survey data are potentially subjected to both recall bias and small sample bias owing to the infrequency with which some healthcare payments are made. Secondly, our conventional measures of progressivity provide no information on those citizens who cannot afford to use health services and have incurred no health expenditures. Thirdly, the present study does not examine the obvious impact of OOP payments on the quantity and quality of care consumed. Our interpretations, therefore, need to be complemented by studies of health care utilization [29] and the incidence of public finance [30]. Finally, our analysis does not capture all potentially catastrophic effects of illness or disability, such as lost earnings, and does not investigate whether health shocks are absorbed by incurring debt or expending savings to smooth consumption [31].

Conclusions

Our findings substantially add to the evidence on the regressivity of HSF in Bangladesh. This macro-level data analysis shows that there is heavy reliance on OOP payments, which exceed 63.0% of the total health expenditure. Further, this heavy reliance on OOP payments reduces household living standards and may lead to poverty or ultimately push households to deeper poverty.
Regressivity of Bangladesh HSF is mostly related to the high OOP and the absence of a functional collective prepayment system. Social insurance is very negligible, and private health insurance is present only in some pocket areas run by NGOs. The system urgently needs to introduce health insurance schemes for the poor, elderly, disabled and disadvantaged. Measurable country-specific milestones in monitoring progressivity need to be adopted. The findings of this study can guide policy decisions in this aspect.
Chronic illnesses and household income were found to be the most influential and statistically significant (p < 0.001) predictors of high household healthcare expenditure in Bangladesh [32]. Further, low revenue generating ability of the government of Bangladesh and high OOP expenditures make a risk pooling and prepayment system an absolute necessity. The Bangladesh Health Care Financing Strategy (HCFS), 2012–2032 recommends a national health protection scheme [33]. The scheme targets mainly the formal sectors of the country with compulsory payroll taxation. People below the poverty line would be subsidized from the general revenue. It would allow the informal sector to join the scheme voluntarily. Health cards have some positive effect on OOP payments [34]. Thailand introduced an identity card named “Health Card” in 1983 to protect the poor in the community [35]. Australian Health Care Card [36] and Indonesian Health Card Program [37] were introduced for the same purpose. Development of such type of health card may be an option for financial protection of the poor in Bangladesh.
The study findings may contribute to policy making, particularly in relation to the proposed financial risk protection, social protection, and universal coverage. Our findings provide empirical evidence for future healthcare reforms. We hope this research will stimulate more studies of this subject with improved method and analysis.

Acknowledgements

We are thankful to Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics for providing us the dataset on Household Income and Expenditure Survey, 2010. We are deeply thankful to the anonymous reviewers of the journal for their thoughtful and creative comments and suggestions. Our sincere thanks and gratitude to Mr. Cub Kahn for a thorough language edit.

Funding

The study was not funded by any source.

Availability of data and materials

The data is not publicly available. We bought the dataset from Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics for use in our research. We have the analytical files.
We have used a secondary dataset (HIES, 2010). The data has been collected by Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics (BBS). We have taken ethical clearance from institutional review board (IRB), reference number 7453 dated 05/02/2016 of the Oregon State University. As secondary data analysis, it does not deal with any human subject.
Not applicable

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Open AccessThis article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made. The Creative Commons Public Domain Dedication waiver (http://​creativecommons.​org/​publicdomain/​zero/​1.​0/​) applies to the data made available in this article, unless otherwise stated.
Literatur
1.
Zurück zum Zitat Wagstaff A, O'Donnell O, Van Doorslaer E, Lindelow M. Analyzing health equity using household survey data: a guide to techniques and their implementation: World Bank Publications; 2007 Nov 2. Wagstaff A, O'Donnell O, Van Doorslaer E, Lindelow M. Analyzing health equity using household survey data: a guide to techniques and their implementation: World Bank Publications; 2007 Nov 2.
2.
Zurück zum Zitat O'Donnell O, Van Doorslaer E, Wagstaff A, Lindelow M. Analyzing health equity using household survey data: a guide to techniques and their implementation. In: Washington. DC: The World Bank Google Scholar; 2008. p. 2010. O'Donnell O, Van Doorslaer E, Wagstaff A, Lindelow M. Analyzing health equity using household survey data: a guide to techniques and their implementation. In: Washington. DC: The World Bank Google Scholar; 2008. p. 2010.
3.
Zurück zum Zitat Tobin J. On limiting the domain of inequality. The Journal of Law and Economics. 1970 Oct 1;13(2):263–77.CrossRef Tobin J. On limiting the domain of inequality. The Journal of Law and Economics. 1970 Oct 1;13(2):263–77.CrossRef
5.
Zurück zum Zitat Culyer AJ, Wagstaff A. Equity and equality in health and healthcare. J Health Econ. 1993;12:431–57.CrossRefPubMed Culyer AJ, Wagstaff A. Equity and equality in health and healthcare. J Health Econ. 1993;12:431–57.CrossRefPubMed
6.
Zurück zum Zitat Atun R, De Andrade LO, Almeida G, Cotlear D, Dmytraczenko T, Frenz P, Garcia P. Gómez- Dantés O, Knaul FM, Muntaner C, de Paula JB. Health-system reform and universal health coverage in Latin America. Lancet. 2015 Apr 3;385(9974):1230–47.CrossRefPubMed Atun R, De Andrade LO, Almeida G, Cotlear D, Dmytraczenko T, Frenz P, Garcia P. Gómez- Dantés O, Knaul FM, Muntaner C, de Paula JB. Health-system reform and universal health coverage in Latin America. Lancet. 2015 Apr 3;385(9974):1230–47.CrossRefPubMed
7.
Zurück zum Zitat Crivelli L, Salari P. The inequity of the Swiss health care system financing from a federal state perspective. Int J Equity Health. 2014 Feb 14;13(1):17.CrossRefPubMedPubMedCentral Crivelli L, Salari P. The inequity of the Swiss health care system financing from a federal state perspective. Int J Equity Health. 2014 Feb 14;13(1):17.CrossRefPubMedPubMedCentral
8.
Zurück zum Zitat Duran A, Kutzin J, Menabde N. Universal coverage challenges require health system approaches; the case of India. Health policy. 2014 Feb 28;114(2):269–77.CrossRefPubMed Duran A, Kutzin J, Menabde N. Universal coverage challenges require health system approaches; the case of India. Health policy. 2014 Feb 28;114(2):269–77.CrossRefPubMed
9.
Zurück zum Zitat Normand C. Equity in the finance and delivery of health care: an international perspective. Br Med J. 1993 Jul 10;307(6896):140–1.CrossRef Normand C. Equity in the finance and delivery of health care: an international perspective. Br Med J. 1993 Jul 10;307(6896):140–1.CrossRef
11.
Zurück zum Zitat Gilson L. Government health care charges: is equity being abandoned? A discussion paper, 1988. Gilson L. Government health care charges: is equity being abandoned? A discussion paper, 1988.
12.
Zurück zum Zitat Asante A, Price J, Hayen A, Jan S, Wiseman V. Equity in health care financing in low-and middle-income countries: a systematic review of evidence from studies using benefit and financing incidence analyses. PLoS One. 2016 Apr 11;11(4):e0152866.CrossRefPubMedPubMedCentral Asante A, Price J, Hayen A, Jan S, Wiseman V. Equity in health care financing in low-and middle-income countries: a systematic review of evidence from studies using benefit and financing incidence analyses. PLoS One. 2016 Apr 11;11(4):e0152866.CrossRefPubMedPubMedCentral
13.
Zurück zum Zitat Reich MR, Harris J, Ikegami N, Maeda A, Cashin C, Araujo EC, Takemi K, Evans TG. Moving towards universal health coverage: lessons from 11 country studies. Lancet. 2016 Feb 26;387(10020):811–6.CrossRefPubMed Reich MR, Harris J, Ikegami N, Maeda A, Cashin C, Araujo EC, Takemi K, Evans TG. Moving towards universal health coverage: lessons from 11 country studies. Lancet. 2016 Feb 26;387(10020):811–6.CrossRefPubMed
14.
Zurück zum Zitat World Health Organization. Global action plan for the prevention and control of noncommunicable diseases 2013–2020. World Health Organization. Global action plan for the prevention and control of noncommunicable diseases 2013–2020.
15.
Zurück zum Zitat World Health Organization. Sixty-fourth World Health Assembly. Youth and health risks. WHA64. 28. 24 May 2011. World Health Organization. Sixty-fourth World Health Assembly. Youth and health risks. WHA64. 28. 24 May 2011.
17.
Zurück zum Zitat Molla AA, Anwar KS, Hamid SA, Hoque ME, Haq AK. Analysis of disability adjusted life years (DALYs) among arsenic victims: a cross-sectional study on health economics perspective. Bangladesh Med Res Counc Bull. 2004 Aug;30(2):43–50.PubMed Molla AA, Anwar KS, Hamid SA, Hoque ME, Haq AK. Analysis of disability adjusted life years (DALYs) among arsenic victims: a cross-sectional study on health economics perspective. Bangladesh Med Res Counc Bull. 2004 Aug;30(2):43–50.PubMed
18.
Zurück zum Zitat Bangladesh National Health Account 2007-2012. Health economics unit (HEU), Ministry of Health and Family Welfare Government of the People’s Republic of Bangladesh Dhaka, 2012. Bangladesh National Health Account 2007-2012. Health economics unit (HEU), Ministry of Health and Family Welfare Government of the People’s Republic of Bangladesh Dhaka, 2012.
19.
Zurück zum Zitat Majumder MA. World health statistics 2011: how does Bangladesh compare with other south-east Asian countries? South East Asia Journal of Public Health. 2013 Jan 8;1(1):4–11. Majumder MA. World health statistics 2011: how does Bangladesh compare with other south-east Asian countries? South East Asia Journal of Public Health. 2013 Jan 8;1(1):4–11.
21.
Zurück zum Zitat StataCorp. Stata statistical software: release 14. College Station, TX: StataCorp LP; 2015. StataCorp. Stata statistical software: release 14. College Station, TX: StataCorp LP; 2015.
22.
Zurück zum Zitat Bilger M, Sajaia Z, Lokshin M. Health equity and financial protection: streamlined analysis with ADePT software: World Bank Publications; 2011. Bilger M, Sajaia Z, Lokshin M. Health equity and financial protection: streamlined analysis with ADePT software: World Bank Publications; 2011.
23.
Zurück zum Zitat Kakwani NC. Measurement of tax progressivity: an international comparison. Econ J. 1977;87(345):71–80.CrossRef Kakwani NC. Measurement of tax progressivity: an international comparison. Econ J. 1977;87(345):71–80.CrossRef
24.
Zurück zum Zitat Wagstaff A, Van Doorslaer E. Equity in the finance of health care: some international comparisons. J Health Econ. 1992 Dec 1;11(4):361–87.CrossRefPubMed Wagstaff A, Van Doorslaer E. Equity in the finance of health care: some international comparisons. J Health Econ. 1992 Dec 1;11(4):361–87.CrossRefPubMed
25.
Zurück zum Zitat Wagstaff A, Van Doorslaer E, Van der Burg H, Calonge S, Christiansen T, Citoni G, Gerdtham UG, Gerfin M, Gross L, Häkinnen U, Johnson P. Equity in the finance of health care: some further international comparisons. J Health Econ. 1999 Jun 30;18(3):263–90.CrossRefPubMed Wagstaff A, Van Doorslaer E, Van der Burg H, Calonge S, Christiansen T, Citoni G, Gerdtham UG, Gerfin M, Gross L, Häkinnen U, Johnson P. Equity in the finance of health care: some further international comparisons. J Health Econ. 1999 Jun 30;18(3):263–90.CrossRefPubMed
26.
Zurück zum Zitat Van Doorslaer E, Wagstaff A, Van der Burg H, Christiansen T, Citoni G, Di Biase R, Gerdtham UG, Gerfin M, Gross L, Häkinnen U, John J. The redistributive effect of health care finance in twelve OECD countries. J Health Econ. 1999 Jun 30;18(3):291–313.CrossRefPubMed Van Doorslaer E, Wagstaff A, Van der Burg H, Christiansen T, Citoni G, Di Biase R, Gerdtham UG, Gerfin M, Gross L, Häkinnen U, John J. The redistributive effect of health care finance in twelve OECD countries. J Health Econ. 1999 Jun 30;18(3):291–313.CrossRefPubMed
27.
Zurück zum Zitat Mastilica M, Bozikov J. Out-of-pocket payments for health care in Croatia: implications for equity. Croatian Medical Journal. 1999 Jun 1;40:152–9.PubMed Mastilica M, Bozikov J. Out-of-pocket payments for health care in Croatia: implications for equity. Croatian Medical Journal. 1999 Jun 1;40:152–9.PubMed
28.
Zurück zum Zitat Hamid SA, Ahsan SM, Begum A. Disease-specific impoverishment impact of out-of-pocket payments for health care: evidence from rural Bangladesh. Applied health economics and health policy. 2014 Aug 1;12(4):421–33.CrossRefPubMed Hamid SA, Ahsan SM, Begum A. Disease-specific impoverishment impact of out-of-pocket payments for health care: evidence from rural Bangladesh. Applied health economics and health policy. 2014 Aug 1;12(4):421–33.CrossRefPubMed
29.
Zurück zum Zitat Somanathan A, O'Donnell O, et al. Who gets health care in Asia? EQUITAP working paper # 4. Rotterdam and IPS, Colombo: Erasmus University; 2005. Somanathan A, O'Donnell O, et al. Who gets health care in Asia? EQUITAP working paper # 4. Rotterdam and IPS, Colombo: Erasmus University; 2005.
30.
Zurück zum Zitat O'Donnell O, van Doorslaer E, et al. Explaining the incidence of catastrophic expenditures on health care: comparative evidence from Asia. In: EQUITAP working paper #5. Colombo: Eramsus University, Rotterdam and IPS; 2005. O'Donnell O, van Doorslaer E, et al. Explaining the incidence of catastrophic expenditures on health care: comparative evidence from Asia. In: EQUITAP working paper #5. Colombo: Eramsus University, Rotterdam and IPS; 2005.
31.
Zurück zum Zitat Gertler P, Gruber J. Insuring consumption against illness. Am Econ Rev. 2002;92(1):51–70.CrossRef Gertler P, Gruber J. Insuring consumption against illness. Am Econ Rev. 2002;92(1):51–70.CrossRef
32.
Zurück zum Zitat Molla AA, Chi C, Mondaca AL. Predictors of high out-of-pocket healthcare expenditure: an analysis using Bangladesh household income and expenditure survey, 2010. BMC Health Serv Res. 2017 Jan 31;17(1):94.CrossRefPubMedPubMedCentral Molla AA, Chi C, Mondaca AL. Predictors of high out-of-pocket healthcare expenditure: an analysis using Bangladesh household income and expenditure survey, 2010. BMC Health Serv Res. 2017 Jan 31;17(1):94.CrossRefPubMedPubMedCentral
33.
Zurück zum Zitat Expanding social protection for health: towards universal coverage—health care financing strategy 2012–2032, Health economics unit, Ministry of Health and Family Welfare, Dhaka (2012). Expanding social protection for health: towards universal coverage—health care financing strategy 2012–2032, Health economics unit, Ministry of Health and Family Welfare, Dhaka (2012).
34.
Zurück zum Zitat Pradhan M, Prescott N. Social risk management options for medical care in Indonesia. Health Econ. 2002;11:431–46.CrossRefPubMed Pradhan M, Prescott N. Social risk management options for medical care in Indonesia. Health Econ. 2002;11:431–46.CrossRefPubMed
35.
Zurück zum Zitat Pannarunothai S, Srithamrongsawat S, Kongpan M, Thumvanna P. Financing reforms for the Thai health card scheme. Health Policy Plan. 2000;15(3):303–11.CrossRefPubMed Pannarunothai S, Srithamrongsawat S, Kongpan M, Thumvanna P. Financing reforms for the Thai health card scheme. Health Policy Plan. 2000;15(3):303–11.CrossRefPubMed
36.
Zurück zum Zitat Correa-Velez I, Gifford SM, Bice SJ. Australian health policy on access to medical care for refugees and asylum seekers. Australia and New Zealand health policy. 2005;2(1):23.CrossRefPubMedPubMedCentral Correa-Velez I, Gifford SM, Bice SJ. Australian health policy on access to medical care for refugees and asylum seekers. Australia and New Zealand health policy. 2005;2(1):23.CrossRefPubMedPubMedCentral
37.
Zurück zum Zitat Johar M. The impact of the Indonesian health card program: a matching estimator approach. J Health Econ. 2009;28(1):35–53.CrossRefPubMed Johar M. The impact of the Indonesian health card program: a matching estimator approach. J Health Econ. 2009;28(1):35–53.CrossRefPubMed
Metadaten
Titel
Who pays for healthcare in Bangladesh? An analysis of progressivity in health systems financing
verfasst von
Azaher Ali Molla
Chunhuei Chi
Publikationsdatum
01.12.2017
Verlag
BioMed Central
Erschienen in
International Journal for Equity in Health / Ausgabe 1/2017
Elektronische ISSN: 1475-9276
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1186/s12939-017-0654-3

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2017

International Journal for Equity in Health 1/2017 Zur Ausgabe