Skip to main content
Log in

The Control of Invasive Species on Private Property with Neighbor-to-Neighbor Spillovers

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Invasive pests cross property boundaries. Property managers may have private incentives to control invasive species despite not having sufficient incentive to fully internalize the external costs of their role in spreading the invasion. Each property manager has a right to future use of his own property, but his property may abut others’ properties enabling spread of an invasive species. The incentives for a foresighted property manager to control invasive species have received little attention. We consider the efforts of a foresighted property manager who has rights to future use of a property and has the ability to engage in repeated, discrete control activities. We find that higher rates of dispersal, associated with proximity to neighboring properties, reduce the private incentives for control. Controlling species at one location provides incentives to control at a neighboring location. Control at neighboring locations are strategic complements and coupled with spatial heterogeneity lead to a weaker-link public good problem, in which each property owner is unable to fully appropriate the benefits of his own control activity. Future-use rights and private costs suggest that there is scope for a series of Coase-like exchanges to internalize much of the costs associated with species invasion. Pigouvian taxes on invasive species potentially have qualitatively perverse behavioral effects. A tax with a strong income effect (e.g., failure of effective revenue recycling) can reduce the value of property assets and diminish the incentive to manage insects on one’s own property.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Attenuated spatial property rights may also have a finite time horizon.

  2. We refer to spatial property rights and not ownership because it is possible that more limited rights provide incentive for control. For example, a rancher with a grazing right to public land, and the ability to exclude other ranchers, is more likely to control an invasive weed than if the area were grazed as a commons. This is true even though the rancher does not own the range.

  3. Blunt management instruments cannot be used in a continuous way according to equimarginal principle, and many realistic land management instruments fall into this category. When pesticide is sprayed on a per area based the treatment level is not influence by the size of the pest population. Another example is engaging biosecurity measures such as fencing to protect livestock from wildlife carrying disease (Horan et al. 2008).

  4. Brazil and China have also suffered from the spread of ACP-HLB.

  5. http://usda.mannlib.cornell.edu/MannUsda/viewDocumentInfo.do?documentID=1377.

  6. Marten and Moore (2011) allows chemical and bio-control and allows for variation in intensity to assess socially optimal management (since bio-control interventions are seldom done by a single landowner). Sims et al. (2010), and Sims and Finnoff (2012) investigate control of stochastic spread of forest damaging insects.

  7. One advantage of this approach is that in principle it enables the analyst to consider the case of zero insects as a special case of the feedback rule thereby bridging localized control and localized prevention, and avoiding the need to frame the prevention-control question as one of switching regimes (Mehta et al. 2007; Polasky 2010). We do not exploit this property of this setup in the current research, and this extension is left for future work.

  8. This assumption implies that the bio-physical and economic environments have been relatively stable such that the grower has been able to converge to a long-run equilibrium.

  9. We do not consider grove biosecurity, which could affect the introduction of new insects.

  10. Morris et al. (2008) write, “some [growers] know they have greening [HLB] but rather than institute control practices, plan to take whatever profits can be made, then replant [with an alternative crop] or sell the land.”

  11. http://www.nass.usda.gov/Statistics_by_State/Florida/Publications/Citrus/aban/CitAA12.pdf.

  12. Smith et al. (2009b) use a similar setup to model the management of the depreciation of property values associated with beach erosion through beach nourishment using an approach following Hartman (1976). A critical difference between Smith et al. (2009b) and ours study is that Smith et al. (2009b) always reset the beach to the same width, while in our problem a proportion of insects are killed so the post spraying level of insects depends on the pre-spraying population.

  13. Environmental persistence of pesticide could increase the incentives for spraying. Including environmental persistence adds another state variable with nonlinear dynamics to the model. While important for considering for prescriptive purposes, residual pesticide effects likely will not affect our core insights, and would make graphical visualization challenging.

  14. While Eq. (9) can be implemented directly, rewriting the expression in terms of basis functions and employing an alternative, but smoother, function with the same roots, such as the Fischer-Burnmeister function (Sun and Qi 1999), enhances numerical convergence and reduces memory requirements. We are grateful for this recommendation from an anonymous reviewer.

  15. If growers think a cure might be available in the future they may “moth ball” their groves and cease active management, but this does not stop the groves from producing insects.

  16. A 10 % increase in \(\beta \) did not have an observable influence on the boundary given the density of collocation nodes. Figure 3 presents a doubling of \(\beta \) for illustrative purposes.

  17. Moving grower \(j\) farther from grower \(i\), which is essentially what biosecurity measures do, enhances the value of grower \(i\)’s capital, but investments in biosecurity may have different properties than investments in onsite control. Biosecurity may also transfer or shift the externality to neighbors.

  18. This simplifies the problem by eliminating the problem of the optimal time to pay. The La Chatelier principle suggests that if it is optimal for grower \(i\) to make a payment at the appointed time, then freeing the time of the payment can make grower \(i \)no worse off. For the payment to be moved voluntarily to another time, the payment can also not make grower \(j\) worse off. Therefore, a more flexible program would only enhance the likelihood that a payment system is welfare enhancing.

  19. Biosecurity investments that prevent transmission between groves could be a strategic substitute that leads to free-riding. Other research on invasive species prevention and control suggests that actions to prevent invasion may shift risk to others (Warziniack et al. 2011), but spraying abates damages rather than shifting them.

  20. Such an equilibrium is almost certainly unstable when perturbed with heterogeneous local information.

  21. Given the very high levels of ACPs per citrus tree reported in the literature, marginal reductions in citrus stock are likely to have little effect on the ACP stock. Therefore, marginal reductions in citrus stock in response to a tax are highly unlikely.

  22. Antidotal evidence from Florida suggests livestock grazing under abandoned citrus tress is one potential alternative land use.

References

  • Adda J, Cooper R (2003) Dynamic economics, quantitative methods plus applications. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Aubert B (1987) Trioza erytreae Del Guercio and Diaphorina citri Kuwayama (Homoptera: Psylloidea), two vectors of the citrus greening disease: biological aspects and possible control strategies. Fruits 42:149–162

    Google Scholar 

  • Aubert B (1992) High density planting (HDP) of jiaogan mandarine in the lowland area of Shantou (Guangdong China) and implications for greening control. Proceedings of the Asia Pacific international conference on citriculture, Chiang Mai, Thialand, pp 149–157

  • Aubert B, Quilici S (1987) Monitoring adult psyllas on yellow traps in Reunion island. Tenth conference of the international organization of citrus virologists

  • Balikcioglu M, Fackler PL, Pindyck RS (2011) Solving optimal timing problems in environmental economics. Resour Energy Econ 33:761–768

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird PJWN (1987) The transferability and depletability of externalities. J Environ Econ Manag 14:54–57

    Google Scholar 

  • Born W, Rauschmayer F, Brauer I (2005) Economic evaluation of biological invasions—a survey. Ecol Econ 55:321–336

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S (2004) Microeconomics behavior. Insitutions and evolution. Princeton University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Burnett KM (2006) Introductions of invasive species: failure of the weaker link. Agric Resour Econ Rev 35:21–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Caputo MR (2005) Foundations of dynamic economic analysis: optimal control theory and applications. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Catling HD (1970) Distribution of the psyllid vectors of citrus greening disease, with notes of the biology and bionomics of Diaphorina citri. FAO Plant Prot Bull 18:8–15

    Google Scholar 

  • Ceddia MG, Heikkila J, Peltola J (2009) Managing invasive alien species with professional and hobby farmers: insights from ecological-economic modelling. Ecol Econ 68:1366–1374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiyaka C, Singer BH, Halbert SE, Morris JG, van Bruggen AHC (2012) Modeling huanglongbing transmission within a citrus tree. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 109:12213–12218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1960) The problem of social cost. J Law Econ 3:1–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cocco A, Hoy MA (2008) Toxicity of organosilicone adjuvants and selected pesticides to the Asian citrus psyllid (Hempitera: Psyllidae) and its parasitoid Tamarixia radiata (Hymenoptera: Eulophidae). Fla Entomol 91:610–620

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornes R (1993) Dyke maintenance and other stories: some neglected types of public goods. Q J Econ 108:259–271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costello CJ, Kaffine D (2008) Natural resource use with limited-tenure property rights. J Environ Econ Manag 55:20–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Couture S, Reynaud A (2011) Forest management under fire risk when forest carbon sequestration has value. Ecol Econ 70:2002–2011

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond PA (1982) Aggregate demand management in search equilibrium. J Polit Econ 90:881–894

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit AK, Pindyck RS (1994) Investment under uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Eiswerth ME, Johnson WS (2002) Managing nonindigenous invasive species: insights from dynamic analysis. Environ Resour Econ 23:319–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epanchin-Niell RS, Wilen JE (2012) Optimal spatial control of biological invasions. J Environ Econ Manag 63:260–270

    Google Scholar 

  • Fenichel EP (2013) Economic considerations for social distancing and behavioral based policies during an epidemic. J Health Econ 32:440–451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fenichel EP, Horan RD, Hickling GJ (2010) Bioeconomic management of invasive insect-vectored diseases. Biol Invasions 12:2877–2893

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fenichel EP, Castillo-Chavez C, Ceddia MG, Chowell G, Hickling GJ, Holloway G, Horan R, Morin B, Perrings C, Springborn M, Velazquez L, Villalobos C (2011) Adaptive human behavior in epidemiological models. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 108:6306–6311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finnoff D, Shogren JF, Leung B, Lodge DM (2007) Take a risk: preferring prevention over control of biological invaders. Ecol Econ 62:216–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francis PJ (1997) Dynamic epidemiology and the market for vaccinations. J Public Econ 63:383–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaff H, Joshi HR, Lenhart S (2007) Optimal harvesting during an invasion of a sublethal plant pathogen. Environ Devel Econ 12:673–686

    Google Scholar 

  • Geaun JC (1993) On the shiftable externalities. J Environ Econ Manag 24:30–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Goetz RU, Zilberman D (2000) The dynamcis of spatial pollution: the case of phosphorus runoff from agricultural land. J Econ Dyn Control 24:143–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gottwald TR (2010) Current epidemiological understanding of citrus huanglongbing. Annu Rev Phytopathol 48:110–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gramig BM, Horan RD (2011) Jointly-determined livestock disease dynamics and decentralised economic behavior. Aust J Agric Resour Econ 55:1–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Gramig BM, Horan RD, Wolf C (2009) Livestock disease indemnity design when moral hazard is followed by adverse selection. Am J Agric Econ 91:627–641

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halbert SE, Manjunath KL (2004) Asian citrus psyllid (Sternorrhyncha: Psyllidae) and greening disease of citrus: a literature review and assessment of risk in Florida. Fla Entomol 87:330–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall DG, Hentz MG (2011) Seasonal flight activity by the Asian citrus psyllid in east central Florida. Entomol Exp Appl 139:75–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen LG (2002) Shiftable externalities: a market solution. Environ Resour Econ 21:221–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen ZK, Libecap GD (2004) Small farms, externalities, and the dust bowl of the 1930s. J Polit Econ 112:665–694

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartman R (1976) The harvesting decision when a standing forest has value. Econ Inq 14:52–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmes TC, Liebhold AM, Kovacs KF, Von Holle B (2010) A spatial-dynamic value transfer model of economic losses from a biological invasion. Ecol Econ 70:86–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Homans F, Horie T (2011) Optimal detection strategies for an established invasive pest. Ecol Econ 70:1129–1138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horan RD, Perrings C, Lupi F, Bulte EH (2002) Biological pollution prevention strategies under ignorance: the case of invasive species. Am J Agric Econ 84:1303–1310

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horan RD, Wolf CA, Fenichel EP, Mathews KHJ (2005) Spatial management of wildlife disease. Rev Agric Econ 27:483–490

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horan RD, Wolf CA, Fenichel EP, Mathews KHJ (2008) Joint management of wildlife and livestock disease. Environ Resour Econ 41:47–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knowler D (2005) Reassessing the costs of biological invasion: Mnemiopsis leidyi in the Black sea. Ecol Econ 52:187–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leung B, Finnoff D, Shogren JF, Lodge DM (2005) Managing invasive species: rules of thumb for rapid assessment. Ecol Econ 55:24–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lovell SJ, Stone SF, Fernandez L (2006) The economic impacts of aquatic invasive species: a review of the literature. Agric Resour Econ Rev 35:195–208

    Google Scholar 

  • Lui Y, Tsai J (2000) Effects of temperature on biology and life table parameters of the Asian citrus psyllid, Diaphorina citri Kuwayama (Homoptera: Psyllidae). Ann Appl Biol 137:201–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marten AL, Moore CC (2011) An options based bioeconomic model for biological and chemical control of invasive species. Ecol Econ 70:2050–2061

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehta SV, Haight RG, Homans FR, Polasky S, Venette RC (2007) Optimal detection and control strategies for invasive species management. Ecol Econ 61:234–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miranda MJ, Fackler PL (2002) Applied computation economics and finance. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Morris RA, Murano RP, Spreen TH (2008) Invasive diseases and fruit tree production: economic tradeoffs of citrus greening control on Florida’s citrus industry. Southern Agricultural Economics Association Annual Meeting, Dallas, TX

  • Muller NZ, Mendelsohn R (2009) Efficient pollution regulation: getting the prices right. Am Econ Rev 99:1714–1739

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Connell NV, Kallsen CE, Klonsky KM, De Moura RL, (2009) Sample costs to establish and orange orchard and produce oranges, San Joaquin Valley South, University of California Cooperative Extension, Davis, CA, p 25

  • Perrings C, Fenichel EP, Kinzig AP (2010) Globalization and invasive alien species: trade, pests, and pathogens. In: Mooney H, Williamson M, Perrings C (eds) Bioinvasions and globalization. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 42–55

    Google Scholar 

  • Pimentel D, Lach L, Zuniga R, Morrison D (2000) Environmental and economic costs of nonindigenous species in the United States. BioScience 50:53–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polasky S (2010) A model of prevention, detection, and control for invasive species. In: Mooney H, Williamson M, Perrings C (eds) Bioinvasions and globalization. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 100–107

    Google Scholar 

  • Potapov A (2009) Stochastic model of lake system invasion and its optimal control: neurodynamic programming as a solution method. Nat Resour Model 22:257–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potapov A, Lewis MA, Finnoff D (2007) Optimal control of biological invasions in lake networks. Nat Resour Model 20:351–379

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richards TJ (2009) California citrus in 2009: impact analysis and policy simulation. Report prepared for the California Citrus Mutual, Exeter, CA

  • Richards TJ, Ellsworth P, Tronstad R, Naranjo S (2010) Market-based instruments for the optimal control of invasive insect species: B. Tabaci in Arizona. J Agric Resour Econ 34:349–367

    Google Scholar 

  • Richards TJ, Shanafelt D, Fenichel EP (in press) Foreclosures and invasive insect spread: the case of the Asian citrus psyllid. Am J Agric Econ

  • Roberts MG, Smith G, Grenfell BT (1995) Mathematical models for macroparasites of wildlife. In: Grenfell BT, Dobson AP (eds) Ecology of infectious diseases in natural populations. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp 177–208

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Rogers ME, Stansley PA, Stelinski LL (2011) Florida citrus pest management guide: Asian citrus psyllid and citrus leafminer. University of Florida IFAS Extension, Gainsville, FL

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanchirico JN, Wilen JE (1999) Bioeconomics of spatial exploitation in a patchy environment. J Environ Econ Manag 37:129–150

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandmo A (1975) Optimal taxation in the presence of externalities. Swed J Econ 77:86–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saphores J-DM (2000) The economic threshold with a stochastic pest population: a real options approach. Am J Agric Econ 82:541–555

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Setamou M, Rodriguez D, Saldana R, Schwarzlose G, Palrang D, Nelson SD (2010) Efficacy and uptake of soil-applied imidacloprid in the control of asian citrus psyllid and citrus leafminer, two foliar-feeding citrus pests. J Econ Entomol 103:1711–1719

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharov AA (2004) Bioeconomics of managing the spread of exotic pest species with barrier zones. Risk Anal 24:879–892

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharov AA, Liebhold AM (1998) Bioeconomics of managing the spread of exotic pest species with barrier zones. Ecol Appl 8:833–845

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaw D, Shaw R-D (1991) The resistibility and shiftability of depletable externalities. J Environ Econ Manag 20:224–233

    Google Scholar 

  • Shogren JF, Crocker TD (1991) Cooperative and noncooperative protection against transferable adn filterable externalities. Environ Resour Econ 1:195–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sims C, Aadland D, Finnoff D (2010) A dynamic bioeconomic analysis of mountain pine beetle epidemics. J Econ Dyn Control 34:2407–2419

    Google Scholar 

  • Sims C, Finnoff D (2012) The role of spatial scale in the timing of uncertain environmental policy. J Econ Dyn Control 36:369–382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith MD, Sanchirico JN, Wilen JE (2009a) The economics of spatial-dynamic processes: applications to renewable resources. J Environ Econ Manag 57:104–121

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith MD, Slott JM, McNamara D, Murray AB (2009b) Beach nourishment as a dynamic capital accumulation problem. J Environ Econ Manag 58:58–71

    Google Scholar 

  • Stavins RN (2011) The problem of the commons: still unsettled after 100 years. Am Econ Rev 101:81–108

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun D, Qi L (1999) On NCP-functions. Comput Optim Appl 13:201–220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsai JH, Liu YH (2000) Biology of Diaphorina citri (Homoptera: Psyllidae) on four host plants. J Econ Entomol 93:1721–1725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • USDA NASS (2012) 2012 California land values and cash rents release. United States Department of Agriculture National Agricultural Statistics Service, Sacramento, CA

  • Van den Berg MA, Deacon DE, Thomas CD (1991) Ecology of the citrus psylla, Trioza erytreae (Hemiptera: Triozidae). Phytophylactica 23:195–200

    Google Scholar 

  • Vlassenbroeck J, Van Dooren R (1988) A Chebyshev technique for solving nonlinear optimal control problems. IEEE Trans Autom Control 33:333–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Warziniack T, Finnoff D, Bossenbroek J, Shogren JF, Lodge D (2011) Stepping stones for biological invasion: a bioeconomic model of tranferable risk. Environ Resour Econ 50:605–627

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xepapadeas A (2010) The spatial dimension in environmental and resource economics. Environ Devel Econ 15:747–758

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xu H, Ding H, Li M, Qiang S, Guo J, Han Z, Huang Z, Sun H, He S, Wu H, Wan F (2006) The distribution and economic losses of alien species invasion to China. Biol Invasions 8:1495–1500

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The funding support for the paper is: We thank David Finnoff and two anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments. This publication was made possible by Grant Number 1R01GM100471-01 from the National Institute of General Medical Sciences (NIGMS) at the National Institutes of Health, by the United States Department of Agriculture, Specialty Crop Research Initiative (USDA-SCRI) Award Number 2010-51181-21246, an award from the Saguaro high performance computing center at Arizona State University, and support from Yale’s high performance computing services. Its contents are solely the responsibility of the authors and do not represent the official views of NIGMS or USDA.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eli P. Fenichel.

Appendix

Appendix

The choice of \(\beta \) is dependent on the extent to which HLB is present, which can be highly variable even within infected regions (Gottwald 2010). Our choice of \(\beta \) reflects a limited amount of HLB (Halbert and Manjunath 2004) and is within the range implied by Chiyaka et al. (2012). The net growth rate of ACP is highly variable and dependent on environmental conditions. Our choice falls within the range from the literature (Lui and Tsai 2000; Tsai and Liu 2000). The rate is lower than the average growth rate used by Chiyaka et al. (2012), but their growth model enables the net growth rate to change seasonally. This is why their model enables a longer persistence of citrus trees. Our growth rate is also reduced relative to the estimate provided by Richards et al. (in press), but still seems to give realistic results. The carrying capacity conversion coefficient, \(b\), was chosen to be realistic but conservative by envisioning 10,000 ACP per tree as a maximal density, which is substantially lower than values reported in the literature, and a square grove with approximately 31 trees on a side.

The profitability parameter \(q\) was chosen so that growers were not too profitable, but that in the absence of ACP and HLB operations are a rational enterprise. Data from the University of California extension office suggests that citrus operations are at best marginally profitable (O’Connell et al. 2009). Spraying costs are often computed on a per acre bases and can be highly variable (Aubert 1987; Catling 1970; Cocco and Hoy 2008). Therefore, our choice of \(c\) is chosen to match in a realistic way with the choice of \(q\), though our parameter is likely on the low side of costs. The technical spraying parameter \(\alpha \) comes from (Setamou et al. 2010).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Fenichel, E.P., Richards, T.J. & Shanafelt, D.W. The Control of Invasive Species on Private Property with Neighbor-to-Neighbor Spillovers. Environ Resource Econ 59, 231–255 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9726-z

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9726-z

Keywords

Navigation