Skip to main content
Erschienen in: International Journal of Health Economics and Management 3-4/2013

01.12.2013

Regulated medical fee schedule of the Japanese health care system

verfasst von: Makoto Kakinaka, Ryuta Ray Kato

Erschienen in: International Journal of Health Economics and Management | Ausgabe 3-4/2013

Einloggen, um Zugang zu erhalten

Abstract

This study presents a theoretical framework for examining the effect of the Japanese government-regulated medical price schedule, ‘Shinryo-Houshu-Seido,’ on the behavior of medical providers. In particular, we discuss the optimal rule of this price schedule for the regulator, taking into account information asymmetry between the regulator and providers. Our simple model predicts that heterogeneous providers either under-provide or over-provide medical inputs in comparison with the socially optimal outcome. Moreover, our results show that when the allocated budget is reduced to a certain level, even the second-best outcome becomes unachievable, no matter how the price schedule is regulated. While the limited budget size is shown to have a clear negative effect on social welfare, we suggest that the prospect of obtaining the second-best outcome is left to negotiation between the regulator and the budget allocator.
Fußnoten
1
The SHS is based on a point system in which the government allocates points to all items covered by the public health insurance.
 
2
Wagstaff (2007) summarizes the features of the Japanese health care system in comparison with other Asian countries. See also Tokita (2002); Ikegami and Campbell (1999, 2004), and Naito (2006), for details.
 
3
In practice, the fee schedule is revised biennially at the Central Social Insurance Medical Council, which is a committee within the MHLW.
 
4
Many theoretical studies examine various issues related to payment systems such as prospective and cost-based payment systems (Newhouse 1983, 1996; Ellis and McGuire 1986, 1988, 1990, 1993; Dranove 1987; Pope 1989; Selden 1990; Allen and Gertler 1991; Glazer and McGuire 1994; Rogerson 1994; Ma 1994; Ma and McGuire 1997; Chalkley and Malcomson 1998; Ellis 1998; Lewis and Sappington 1999; Bos and Fraja 2002; Beitia 2003; Boadway et al. 2004; Mougeot and Naegelen 2005; Siciliani 2006, and Wright 2007). Several studies apply mechanism-design approaches to investigate the health care system with information asymmetry (Lewis and Sappington 1999 and Beitia 2003). See also McGuire (2000), and Dranove and Satterthwaite (2000) for the literature review.
 
5
Grabowski and Vernon (1992); Jacobson et al. (2006), and O’Malley et al. (2006) discuss the relationship between the prices of medical inputs and the reimbursement schemes. Ii and Ohkusa (2002) examine the price sensitivity of demand for primary care services in Japan.
 
6
Our model contains several similar elements as that of Liu and Ma (2012), such as altruistic physicians and consumers’ illness severity. Their model considers the role of the delegation regime of health insurance, where an insurance company establishes a payment contract with the physician, and an insurance contract with the consumer. However, this system is totally different from the Japanese heath care system. In Japan, central government regulates the prices and the financing system. All citizens are covered by a mandatory employment-based health insurance operating on non-profit basis (see Anabacken (1994)).
 
7
Iizuka (2007) also argues that physicians consider more financial burdens of their patients than their own profits. Iizuka (2009) investigates the behavior of pharmaceutical firms which produce generic drugs in the regulated Japanese pharmaceutical market.
 
8
We categorize hospitals and physicians as the medical provider in this paper. We do explicitly not consider the relationship between physicians and hospitals, since we believe that such a relationship is less relevant in the Japanese health care system. We do not discuss the behavior of insurers either, since the role of insurers is very limited in the current Japanese system, as pointed out by Tokita (2002). Regarding the relationship between physicians and hospitals, see Tirole (1988) within the context of the vertical control, and also see Pauly and Redisch (1973); Shortell et al. (1985); Custer et al. (1990); Dor and Watson (1995); Boadway et al. (2004), and Crainich et al. (2008).
 
9
Our model assumes two medical inputs: one input is cheaper than the other, and it is less effective. An example may be the case of generic and brand-name drugs. Other examples may include the case of an old type and a new type of treatments in terms of various aspects, such as the installment of new medical facilities. The old type is generally cheaper than the new type, and it is less expensive.
 
10
The Japanese health care system has mainly been based on the fee-for-service scheme. Many medical services are reimbursed based on the fee-for-service scheme, while there are several hospitals which adopt the prospective reimbursement scheme with the DPC (Diagnosis Procedure Combination) as a framework of Japan’s specific DRG.
 
11
This model assumes that a new medical input recovers a patient completely, while an old medical input recovers a patient partially. The ineffectiveness of an old medical input is captured by \(\theta -\alpha \uplambda \), so that more severe patients face a larger payoff loss. There may be some alternative ways. For example, \(h(0,\uplambda )=\theta -\alpha \uplambda \) for an old medical input, and \(h(1,\uplambda )=\theta +\alpha \uplambda \) for a new medical input. This setting implies that the effectiveness of an old medical input is decreasing in the severity of the health status, while that of a new medical input is increasing in the severity of the health status. However, the qualitative implication would be the same as our assumed model. Thus, we simply assume that \(\uplambda \) affects the health-related payoff only when an old medical input is chosen.
 
12
In our setting, providers care about the effectiveness of medical inputs they provide as well as the cost (co-payments) of medical inputs which their patients have to pay. The inclusion of patients’ co-payments in the payoff of providers is consistent with the argument of Lundin (2000) that physicians take into account patients’ costs significantly when they prescribe. Iizuka (2007) empirically finds that physicians consider patient’s out-of-pocket costs in the prescription drug market in Japan.
 
13
The fee schedule, or points allocated to all items covered by the public health insurance, are revised biennially at the Central Social Insurance Medical Council. Points set to a newly developed, or a brand-name drug, are usually higher than those to an existing one, although the medical effect of a newly developed drug is similar to that of an existing one, in order to cover the research and development cost of the newly developed drug. Furthermore, points set to an existing one is usually decreased at the biennial revision of the fee schedule when a newly developed drug appears. See Ikegami and Campbell (2004) and Iizuka (2007, 2009).
 
14
Ihori et al. (2011) evaluate the reforms of the Japanese public health insurance started in year 2006 in the dynamic general equilibrium framework with overlapping generations, where the effect of government deficits is explicitly considered.
 
15
To reduce the total amount of reimbursements, the regulator controls prices of medical inputs. This would also affect the pharmaceutical industry. Kurata (2009) points out the relationship between the existing SHS and firms’ profitability and argues that high prices of brand-name drugs have induced strong incentives in the pharmaceutical industry to invest in the development of new and competitive drugs. However, our analysis has not incorporated the role of pharmaceutical firms and the relationship between medical providers and the pharmaceutical industry in Japan, which should be addressed in the future research.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Allen, R., & Gertler, P. (1991). Regulation and the provision of quality to heterogeneous consumers: The case of prospective pricing of medical services. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 3, 361–375.CrossRef Allen, R., & Gertler, P. (1991). Regulation and the provision of quality to heterogeneous consumers: The case of prospective pricing of medical services. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 3, 361–375.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Anabacken, O. (1994). Japanese hospitals—culture and competition: A study of ten hospitals. International Journal of Health Planning and Management., 9, 87–101.CrossRef Anabacken, O. (1994). Japanese hospitals—culture and competition: A study of ten hospitals. International Journal of Health Planning and Management., 9, 87–101.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Beitia, A. (2003). Hospital quality choice and market structure in a regulated duopoly. Journal of Health Economics, 22, 1011–1036.PubMedCrossRef Beitia, A. (2003). Hospital quality choice and market structure in a regulated duopoly. Journal of Health Economics, 22, 1011–1036.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Boadway, R., Marchand, M., & Sato, M. (2004). An optimal contract approach to hospital financing. Journal of Health Economics, 23, 85–110.PubMedCrossRef Boadway, R., Marchand, M., & Sato, M. (2004). An optimal contract approach to hospital financing. Journal of Health Economics, 23, 85–110.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bos, D., & De Fraja, G. (2002). Quality and outside capacity in the provision of health services. Journal of Public Economics, 84, 199–218.CrossRef Bos, D., & De Fraja, G. (2002). Quality and outside capacity in the provision of health services. Journal of Public Economics, 84, 199–218.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chalkley, M., & Malcomson, J. M. (1998). Contracting for health services when patient demand does not reflect quality. Journal of Health Economics, 17, 1–19.PubMedCrossRef Chalkley, M., & Malcomson, J. M. (1998). Contracting for health services when patient demand does not reflect quality. Journal of Health Economics, 17, 1–19.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Coscelli, A. (2000). The importance of doctors’ and patients’ preferences in the prescription decision. Journal of Industrial Economics, 48, 349–369.CrossRef Coscelli, A. (2000). The importance of doctors’ and patients’ preferences in the prescription decision. Journal of Industrial Economics, 48, 349–369.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Crainich, D., Leleu, H., & Mauleon, A. (2008). The optimality of hospital financing system: The role of physician-manager interactions. International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, 8, 245–256.PubMedCrossRef Crainich, D., Leleu, H., & Mauleon, A. (2008). The optimality of hospital financing system: The role of physician-manager interactions. International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, 8, 245–256.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Custer, W. S., Moser, J. W., Musacchio, R. A., & Willike, R. J. (1990). The production of health care services and changing hospital reimbursement: The role of hospital-medical staff relationships. Journal of Industrial Economics, 9, 167–192. Custer, W. S., Moser, J. W., Musacchio, R. A., & Willike, R. J. (1990). The production of health care services and changing hospital reimbursement: The role of hospital-medical staff relationships. Journal of Industrial Economics, 9, 167–192.
Zurück zum Zitat Dor, A., & Watson, H. (1995). The hospital-physician interaction in U.S. hospitals: Evolving payment schemes and their incentives. European Economic Review, 39, 795–802.CrossRef Dor, A., & Watson, H. (1995). The hospital-physician interaction in U.S. hospitals: Evolving payment schemes and their incentives. European Economic Review, 39, 795–802.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dranove, D. (1987). Rate-setting by diagnosis related groups and hospital specialization. RAND Journal of Economics, 18, 417–427.CrossRef Dranove, D. (1987). Rate-setting by diagnosis related groups and hospital specialization. RAND Journal of Economics, 18, 417–427.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dranove, D., & Satterthwaite, M. A. (2000). The industrial organization of health care markets. In A. J. Culyer & J. P. Newhouse (Eds.), Handbook of Health Economics (Vol. 1B). Amsterdam: North Holland. Dranove, D., & Satterthwaite, M. A. (2000). The industrial organization of health care markets. In A. J. Culyer & J. P. Newhouse (Eds.), Handbook of Health Economics (Vol. 1B). Amsterdam: North Holland.
Zurück zum Zitat Ellis, R. P. (1998). Creaming, skimping and dumping: Provider competition on the intensive and extensive margins. Journal of Health Economics, 17, 537–555.PubMedCrossRef Ellis, R. P. (1998). Creaming, skimping and dumping: Provider competition on the intensive and extensive margins. Journal of Health Economics, 17, 537–555.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ellis, R. P., & McGuire, T. G. (1986). Provider behaviour under prospective reimbursement. Journal of Health Economics, 5, 129–151.PubMedCrossRef Ellis, R. P., & McGuire, T. G. (1986). Provider behaviour under prospective reimbursement. Journal of Health Economics, 5, 129–151.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ellis, R. P., & McGuire, T. G. (1988). Insurance principles and the design of prospective payment systems. Journal of Health Economics, 7, 215–237.PubMedCrossRef Ellis, R. P., & McGuire, T. G. (1988). Insurance principles and the design of prospective payment systems. Journal of Health Economics, 7, 215–237.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ellis, R. P., & McGuire, T. G. (1990). Optimal payment systems for health services. Journal of Health Economics, 9, 375–396.PubMedCrossRef Ellis, R. P., & McGuire, T. G. (1990). Optimal payment systems for health services. Journal of Health Economics, 9, 375–396.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ellis, R. P., & McGuire, T. G. (1993). Supply-side and demand-side cost sharing in health care. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7, 135–151.PubMedCrossRef Ellis, R. P., & McGuire, T. G. (1993). Supply-side and demand-side cost sharing in health care. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7, 135–151.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Evans, R. G. (1974). Supplier-induced demand: Some empirical evidence and implications. In M. Perlman (Ed.), The Economics of Health and Medical Care. London: Macmillan. Evans, R. G. (1974). Supplier-induced demand: Some empirical evidence and implications. In M. Perlman (Ed.), The Economics of Health and Medical Care. London: Macmillan.
Zurück zum Zitat Glazer, J., & McGuire, T. G. (1994). Payer competition and cost shifting in health care. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 3(1), 71–92.CrossRef Glazer, J., & McGuire, T. G. (1994). Payer competition and cost shifting in health care. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 3(1), 71–92.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grabowski, H. G., & Vernon, J. M. (1992). Brand royalty, entry and price competition in pharmaceuticals after the 1984 drug reform act. Journal of Law and Economics, 35, 331–350.CrossRef Grabowski, H. G., & Vernon, J. M. (1992). Brand royalty, entry and price competition in pharmaceuticals after the 1984 drug reform act. Journal of Law and Economics, 35, 331–350.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hellerstein, J. K. (1998). The importance of the physician in the generic versus trade-name prescription decision. RAND Journal of Economics, 29, 108–136.PubMedCrossRef Hellerstein, J. K. (1998). The importance of the physician in the generic versus trade-name prescription decision. RAND Journal of Economics, 29, 108–136.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ihori, T., Kato, R. R., Kawade, M., & Bessho, S. (2011). Health insurance reform and economic growth: Simulation analysis in Japan. Japan and the World Economy, 23(4), 227–239.CrossRef Ihori, T., Kato, R. R., Kawade, M., & Bessho, S. (2011). Health insurance reform and economic growth: Simulation analysis in Japan. Japan and the World Economy, 23(4), 227–239.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ii, M., & Ohkusa, Y. (2002). Price sensitivity of the demand for medical services for minor ailments: Econometric estimates using information on illnesses and symptoms. Japanese Economic Review, 53, 154–166.CrossRef Ii, M., & Ohkusa, Y. (2002). Price sensitivity of the demand for medical services for minor ailments: Econometric estimates using information on illnesses and symptoms. Japanese Economic Review, 53, 154–166.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Iizuka, T. (2007). Expert’s agency problems: Evidence from the prescription drug market in Japan. RAND Journal of Economics, 38, 844–862.PubMedCrossRef Iizuka, T. (2007). Expert’s agency problems: Evidence from the prescription drug market in Japan. RAND Journal of Economics, 38, 844–862.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Iizuka, T. (2009). Generic entry in a regulated pharmaceutical market. Japanese Economic Review, 60, 63–81.CrossRef Iizuka, T. (2009). Generic entry in a regulated pharmaceutical market. Japanese Economic Review, 60, 63–81.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ikegami, N., & Campbell, J. C. (1999). Health care reform in Japan: The virtues of muddling through. Health Affairs, 18, 56–75.PubMedCrossRef Ikegami, N., & Campbell, J. C. (1999). Health care reform in Japan: The virtues of muddling through. Health Affairs, 18, 56–75.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ikegami, N., & Campbell, J. C. (2004). Japan’s health care system: Containing costs and attempting reform. Health Affairs, 23, 26–36.PubMedCrossRef Ikegami, N., & Campbell, J. C. (2004). Japan’s health care system: Containing costs and attempting reform. Health Affairs, 23, 26–36.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jacobson, M., O’Malley, A. J., Earle, C. C., Pakes, J., Gaccione, P., & Newhouse, J. P. (2006). Does reimbursement influence chemotherapy treatment for cancer patients? Health Affairs, 25, 437–443.PubMedCrossRef Jacobson, M., O’Malley, A. J., Earle, C. C., Pakes, J., Gaccione, P., & Newhouse, J. P. (2006). Does reimbursement influence chemotherapy treatment for cancer patients? Health Affairs, 25, 437–443.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kurata, K. (2009). The development of new drugs in the Japanese pharmaceutical industry (in Japanese). RIETI Highlight, 28, 10–13. Kurata, K. (2009). The development of new drugs in the Japanese pharmaceutical industry (in Japanese). RIETI Highlight, 28, 10–13.
Zurück zum Zitat Lewis, T., & Sappington, D. (1999). Using subjective risk adjusting to prevent patient dumping in the health care industry. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 8, 351–382.CrossRef Lewis, T., & Sappington, D. (1999). Using subjective risk adjusting to prevent patient dumping in the health care industry. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 8, 351–382.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Liu, T., & Ma, C.-T. A. (2012). Health insurance, treatment plan, and delegation to altruistic physician. Department of Economics Working Papers, Stony Brook University. Liu, T., & Ma, C.-T. A. (2012). Health insurance, treatment plan, and delegation to altruistic physician. Department of Economics Working Papers, Stony Brook University.
Zurück zum Zitat Liu, Y.-M., Yang, Y.-H. K., & Hsieh, C.-R. (2009). Financial incentives and physicians’ prescription decisions on the choice between brand-name and generic drugs: Evidence from Taiwan. Journal of Health Economics, 28, 341–349.PubMedCrossRef Liu, Y.-M., Yang, Y.-H. K., & Hsieh, C.-R. (2009). Financial incentives and physicians’ prescription decisions on the choice between brand-name and generic drugs: Evidence from Taiwan. Journal of Health Economics, 28, 341–349.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lundin, D. (2000). Moral hazard in physician prescription behavior. Journal of Health Economics, 19, 632–662.CrossRef Lundin, D. (2000). Moral hazard in physician prescription behavior. Journal of Health Economics, 19, 632–662.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ma, C.-T. A. (1994). Health care payment systems: Cost and quality incentives. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 3, 93–112.CrossRef Ma, C.-T. A. (1994). Health care payment systems: Cost and quality incentives. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 3, 93–112.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ma, C.-T. A., & McGuire, T. G. (1997). Optimal health insurance and provider payment. American Economic Review, 87(4), 685–704. Ma, C.-T. A., & McGuire, T. G. (1997). Optimal health insurance and provider payment. American Economic Review, 87(4), 685–704.
Zurück zum Zitat McGuire, A. (1985). The theory of the hospital: A review of the models. Social Science and Medicine, 20(11), 1177–1184.PubMedCrossRef McGuire, A. (1985). The theory of the hospital: A review of the models. Social Science and Medicine, 20(11), 1177–1184.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McGuire, T. (2000). Physician agency. In A. J. Culyer & J. P. Newhouse (Eds.), Handbook of Health Economics (Vol. 1A). Amsterdam: North Holland. McGuire, T. (2000). Physician agency. In A. J. Culyer & J. P. Newhouse (Eds.), Handbook of Health Economics (Vol. 1A). Amsterdam: North Holland.
Zurück zum Zitat Mougeot, M., & Naegelen, F. (2005). Hospital price regulation and expenditure cap policy. Journal of Health Economics, 24, 55–72.PubMedCrossRef Mougeot, M., & Naegelen, F. (2005). Hospital price regulation and expenditure cap policy. Journal of Health Economics, 24, 55–72.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Naito, H. (2006). The Japanese health-care system and reimbursement for dialysis. Peritoneal Dialysis International, 26, 155–161.PubMed Naito, H. (2006). The Japanese health-care system and reimbursement for dialysis. Peritoneal Dialysis International, 26, 155–161.PubMed
Zurück zum Zitat Newhouse, J. P. (1983). Two prospective difficulties with prospective payment of hospitals, or it’s better to be a resident than a patient with a complex problem. Journal of Health Economics, 2, 269–274.PubMed Newhouse, J. P. (1983). Two prospective difficulties with prospective payment of hospitals, or it’s better to be a resident than a patient with a complex problem. Journal of Health Economics, 2, 269–274.PubMed
Zurück zum Zitat Newhouse, J. P. (1996). Reimbursing health plans and health providers: Efficiency in production versus selection. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 1236–1263. Newhouse, J. P. (1996). Reimbursing health plans and health providers: Efficiency in production versus selection. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 1236–1263.
Zurück zum Zitat O’Malley, A. J., Frank, R. G., Kaddis, A., Rothenberg, B. M., & McNeil, B. J. (2006). Impact of alternative interventions on changes in generic dispensing rates. Health Services Research, 41, 1876–1894.PubMedCrossRef O’Malley, A. J., Frank, R. G., Kaddis, A., Rothenberg, B. M., & McNeil, B. J. (2006). Impact of alternative interventions on changes in generic dispensing rates. Health Services Research, 41, 1876–1894.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pauly, M. V., & Redisch, M. (1973). The not-for-profit hospital as a physicians’ cooperative. American Economic Review, 63, 87–99. Pauly, M. V., & Redisch, M. (1973). The not-for-profit hospital as a physicians’ cooperative. American Economic Review, 63, 87–99.
Zurück zum Zitat Pope, G. C. (1989). Hospital nonprice competition and medicare reimbursement policy. Journal of Health Economics, 8, 147–172.PubMedCrossRef Pope, G. C. (1989). Hospital nonprice competition and medicare reimbursement policy. Journal of Health Economics, 8, 147–172.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Poterba, J. (1994). A skeptic’s view of global budget caps. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8, 67–73.PubMedCrossRef Poterba, J. (1994). A skeptic’s view of global budget caps. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8, 67–73.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rogerson, W. P. (1994). Choice of treatment intensities by a non-profit hospital under prospective pricing. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 3, 7–51.CrossRef Rogerson, W. P. (1994). Choice of treatment intensities by a non-profit hospital under prospective pricing. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 3, 7–51.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shortell, S., Morrisey, M. A., & Conrad, D. A. (1985). Economic regulation and hospital behavior: The effects on medical staff organization and hospital-physician relationships. Health Services Research, 20, 597–628.PubMed Shortell, S., Morrisey, M. A., & Conrad, D. A. (1985). Economic regulation and hospital behavior: The effects on medical staff organization and hospital-physician relationships. Health Services Research, 20, 597–628.PubMed
Zurück zum Zitat Siciliani, L. (2006). Selection of treatment under prospective payment systems in the hospital sector. Journal of Health Economics, 25, 479–499.PubMedCrossRef Siciliani, L. (2006). Selection of treatment under prospective payment systems in the hospital sector. Journal of Health Economics, 25, 479–499.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tirole, J. (1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Tirole, J. (1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Tokita, T. (2002). The prospects for reform of the Japanese healthcare system. Pharmacoeconomics, 20, 55–66.PubMedCrossRef Tokita, T. (2002). The prospects for reform of the Japanese healthcare system. Pharmacoeconomics, 20, 55–66.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Van de Ven, W. P. M. M. (1995). Regulated competition in health care: With or without a global budget? European Economic Review, 39, 786–794.CrossRef Van de Ven, W. P. M. M. (1995). Regulated competition in health care: With or without a global budget? European Economic Review, 39, 786–794.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wagstaff, A. (2007). Health systems in East Asia: What can developing countries learn from Japan and the Asian Tigers? Health Economics, 16, 441–456.PubMedCrossRef Wagstaff, A. (2007). Health systems in East Asia: What can developing countries learn from Japan and the Asian Tigers? Health Economics, 16, 441–456.PubMedCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wright, D. J. (2007). Specialist payment schemes and patient selection in private and public hospitals. Journal of Health Economics, 26, 1014–1026.PubMedCrossRef Wright, D. J. (2007). Specialist payment schemes and patient selection in private and public hospitals. Journal of Health Economics, 26, 1014–1026.PubMedCrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Regulated medical fee schedule of the Japanese health care system
verfasst von
Makoto Kakinaka
Ryuta Ray Kato
Publikationsdatum
01.12.2013
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
International Journal of Health Economics and Management / Ausgabe 3-4/2013
Print ISSN: 2199-9023
Elektronische ISSN: 2199-9031
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10754-013-9133-6

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3-4/2013

International Journal of Health Economics and Management 3-4/2013 Zur Ausgabe