Skip to main content
Erschienen in: BMC Health Services Research 1/2007

Open Access 01.12.2007 | Research article

Willingness to pay for social health insurance among informal sector workers in Wuhan, China: a contingent valuation study

verfasst von: Till Bärnighausen, Yuanli Liu, Xinping Zhang, Rainer Sauerborn

Erschienen in: BMC Health Services Research | Ausgabe 1/2007

Abstract

Background

Most of the about 140 million informal sector workers in urban China do not have health insurance. A 1998 central government policy leaves it to the discretion of municipal governments to offer informal sector workers in cities voluntary participation in a social health insurance for formal sector workers, the so-called 'basic health insurance' (BHI).

Methods

We used the contingent valuation method to assess the maximum willingness to pay (WTP) for BHI among informal sector workers, including unregistered rural-to-urban migrants, in Wuhan City, China. We selected respondents in a two-stage self-weighted cluster sampling scheme.

Results

On average, informal sector workers were willing to pay substantial amounts for BHI (30 Renminbi (RMB), 95% confidence interval (CI) 27-33) as well as substantial proportions of their incomes (4.6%, 95% CI 4.1-5.1%). Average WTP increased significantly when any one of the copayments of the BHI was removed in the valuation: to 51 RMB (95% CI 46-56) without reimbursement ceiling; to 43 RMB (95% CI 37-49) without deductible; and to 47 RMB (95% CI 40-54) without coinsurance. WTP was higher than estimates of the cost of BHI based on past health expenditure or on premium contributions of formal sector workers. Predicted coverage with BHI declined steeply with the premium contribution at low contribution levels.
When we applied equity weighting in the aggregation of individual WTP values in order to adjust for inequity in the distribution of income, mean WTP for BHI increased with inequality aversion over a plausible range of the aversion parameter. Holding other factors constant in multiple regression analysis, for a 1% increase in income WTP for BHI with different copayments increased by 0.434-0.499% (all p < 0.0001), and for a 1% increase in past health care expenditure WTP increased by 0.076-0.148% (all p < 0.0004). Being male, a migrant, or without permanent employment significantly decreased WTP for BHI. Education was not a significant determinant of WTP for BHI.

Conclusion

Our results suggest that Chinese municipal governments should allow informal sector workers to participate in the BHI. From a normative perspective, BHI for informal sector workers is likely to increase social welfare because average WTP for BHI is significantly higher than estimates of the average cost of BHI. We further find that informal sector workers do not value the BHI as a mechanism to recover the relatively frequent but small financial losses associated with common illnesses, but because it protects against the rare but large financial losses associated with catastrophic care. From a behavioural perspective, our results predict that at a price equal to the average premium contribution of formal sector workers 35% of informal sector workers will enrol in the BHI. Subsidies and changes in insurance attributes (e.g. including catastrophic care and portability) should be effective in increasing BHI coverage. In addition, coverage should expand with rising incomes among informal sector workers in China. Finally, adverse selection will be unlikely to be a large problem, if the BHI is offered to informal sector workers.
Hinweise

Electronic supplementary material

The online version of this article (doi:10.​1186/​1472-6963-7-114) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

Competing interests

The author(s) declare that they have no competing interests.

Authors' contributions

TB, XZ RS designed the study. TB and XZ carried out the pilot survey and the main survey. TB performed the statistical analysis and drafted the manuscript. YL, XZ and RS were involved in the interpretation of the data and revised the manuscript critically for important intellectual content. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.
Abkürzungen
BHI
Basic Health Insurance
GIS
Government Insurance System
LIS
Labour Insurance System
WTP
willingness to pay
RMB
Renminbi

Background

Health insurance coverage in China's cities is linked to employment. Most formal sector employees are currently covered by one of three social health insurance systems. The Labour Insurance System (LIS, laobao yiliao) and the Government Insurance System (GIS, gongfei yiliao) were established in 1951 and 1952, respectively [1]. The LIS covers workers in large state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and collective-owned enterprises (COEs); the GIS covers current and retired government staff as well as college and university students [24]. In 1998, a third social health insurance for urban formal sector workers, the so-called Basic Health Insurance (BHI, jiben yiliao baoxian), was created by a central government decision. The BHI covers all those who are eligible for LIS or GIS and, additionally, formal workers in private sector companies and smaller public enterprises [58]. The BHI has replaced the LIS and GIS in a number of Chinese cities and should, according to the 1998 decision, completely replace the LIS and GIS in all Chinese cities over time. It has been estimated that in 2003, 27% [9, 10] to 30% [11] of China's 500 million urban residents had BHI coverage and 25% [11] to 27% [9] had other health insurance coverage (including LIS, GIS and commercial health insurance), while between 45% [11] and 46% [9] did not have any health insurance.
In contrast to formal sector workers, most informal sector workers in Chinese cities do not have health insurance. Until the end of the Cultural Revolution in 1976 almost all workers in urban China were employed in the formal sector. Since the Chinese market reforms in the 1980s, however, the number of informal sector workers has risen dramatically as public sector enterprises laid off large numbers of employees and rural-to-urban migration increased. Most laid-off workers and rural-to-urban migrants have found (re-)employment in the informal rather than in the formal sector and are thus not eligible for health insurance coverage either in the GIS, LIS or BHI. Figure 1 shows the changes in employment structure in urban China from 1990 to 2002 based on Ghose (2005) [12]. By 2002, 57% of all urban workers (or 139 million people) were employed in the informal sector. The growth of the informal sector workforce in the past ten years is not unique to China. In many other Asian countries, similar trends have been observed [13].
Lack of health insurance coverage in China impedes access to health care [14]. Chinese health statistics show that 20% of urban residents forgo hospital inpatient care recommended by a health care professional because they are unable to pay for it [15]. Lack of health insurance is also a major cause of poverty in China [16]. A recent survey found that more than 32 million people in China (or 3% of the population) live in poverty (defined as living on less than $1.08 per day at 1993 purchasing power parity) because of out-of-pocket spending for health care [17].
One option to try to ensure that informal sector workers in urban China have access to health care and are protected against the financial risk of health expenditure is to include them in the BHI. The 1998 central government policy on BHI leaves it to the discretion of municipal governments to offer voluntary participation in the BHI to informal sectors workers [5, 7, 18]. To provide urban informal workers, especially rural-to-urban migrants, access to basic health care is one of China's current development priorities [19, 20].
We used the contingent valuation method to assess the maximum willingness to pay (WTP) for BHI among informal sector workers in Wuhan City, China. The BHI as stipulated by the central government decision covers a comprehensive set of in- and outpatient health services with a reimbursement ceiling (i.e. the maximum Renminbi (RMB) amount that the BHI will pay per insured worker in any given year), a deductible (i.e. a fixed RMB amount that the insured person has to pay out-of-pocket in any given year before the BHI starts to make payments for covered benefits), and coinsurance (i.e. the percentage of health expenditure that the insured person has to pay out-of-pocket after the deductible has been paid) [8]. In addition to valuing the BHI as it has been laid out by the central government (henceforth called baseline BHI), we asked respondents to value separately three variations of the BHI (BHI without ceiling, BHI without deductible, and BHI without coinsurance).
Information about WTP for BHI can be used from a normative perspective and a behavioural perspective [21]. The maximum WTP equals the compensating gain, i.e. the income reduction that would maintain a respondent's initial level of utility, if he or she were provided BHI coverage [2224]. From a normative perspective, it can thus be used as a direct measure of the monetary value of the BHI, for instance, in a cost-benefit analysis to inform policy makers about whether it will be socially desirable to provide the BHI to informal sector workers. From a behavioural perspective, demand curves constructed from the WTP results can inform policy makers about the trade-off between insurance coverage and cost recovery if the BHI were offered to informal sector workers in the market place. Our results may further aid in deciding on insurance attributes and designing marketing strategies for the BHI for informal sector workers.

Methods

Contingent valuation method

Contingent valuation is a survey method to elicit the maximum WTP for a good. First, the good and a hypothetical market in which the good can be bought are described to the respondent (the contingency). The respondent is then asked to state the maximum amount s/he would be willing to pay for the good (the valuation). A number of previous studies have used contingent valuation to measure the WTP for health insurance in developing countries, including in rural Burkina Faso [2528], rural Cameroon [29, 30], rural India [31], rural Iran [32], rural Nigeria [33], and Ghana [34]. A recent study has assessed the WTP for private health insurance in four small cities in China (in Shandong Province and Sichuan Province) [35]. This study differs from ours in four important aspects. First, its target population contains all types of registered urban workers, including public and private formal sector workers, while we focus exclusively on informal sector workers. Second, it investigates the WTP for different non-comprehensive private health insurances (insurance for catastrophic diseases vs. inpatient care vs. outpatient care) without copayments, while our study measures the WTP to participate in a comprehensive social health insurance with different copayments. Third, 40% of the sample in the study had public health insurance (i.e. the insurance to be valued is supplementary to public health insurance), while people with health insurance were not eligible to participate in our study. Fourth, the study took place in four small cities (one with a population of 110,000 and three with populations 30,000 – 60,000), while our study took place in one of China's ten largest cities (with a population of 3.9 million in 1999). Chinese small cities differ significantly from large cities. They are much less urbanized and economically developed than large cities [36] and have lower insurance coverage [37].

Choice of WTP question format

We chose the payment card format to elicit WTP values. Respondents were handed a card with a number of monetary values in ascending order and were asked to circle all those monetary values they would be willing to pay for the BHI up to and including the maximum amount. The payment card format was originally developed by Mitchell and Carson [22] and has been used in a number of previous studies evaluating WTP for health care [38]. It has a number of advantages over alternative question formats. Unlike the 'take-it-or-leave it' (TIOLI) format and the bidding game format it does not suffer from starting point bias and unlike the TIOLI format it does not suffer from yeah-saying bias [39]. Theoretically, payment card questions are vulnerable to forms of range bias (i.e. respondents' answers are influenced by the highest monetary value on the card) and mid-point bias (i.e. respondents tend to state their maximum WTP in the middle of the card). However, there is little empirical evidence of the existence of range bias or mid-point bias [40, 41]. In addition, while the payment card method could give rise to 'protest zeros' (i.e. false zero valuations in order to express dissent to some attribute of the WTP question), unlike the open-ended WTP question format it has not been found to lead to a very high proportion of protest-zero responses [4043]. In order to distinguish between protest zeros and true zeros in this survey, all respondents who did not give at least one non-zero response to one of the four WTP questions were asked for the reason for their unwillingness to pay using a multiple choice question with an open-ended category.

Setting and sample

The survey was conducted between September 1999 and January 2000 in Wuhan City, Hubei Province, China. Wuhan is a major port and industrial city in central China located alongside the Yangtze River. We chose Wuhan as the site for this study, because it is typical of the average Chinese city with regard to age composition, educational attainment and income [44]. The survey was conducted by fifteen interviewers who at the time were either graduate or postgraduate students in Public Health at the National Centre for Health Management at Tongji Medical University in Wuhan, China. All of the interviewers had previously taken part in population-based surveys and were specifically trained for the WTP survey. The study was reviewed and approved by the medical ethics committee of Tongji Medical University. Before the main survey was conducted, 65 respondents were interviewed in a pilot survey. As a result of the experiences in the pilot study, some survey questions were changed.
The target population were informal sector workers in Wuhan who were at least 18 years of age but not older than 60 years of age and did not currently have any type of health insurance. We used an operational definition of informal sector workers that is similar to one that has been used in surveys conducted by the International Labour Office, namely own-account workers (excluding administrative workers and professionals), unpaid family workers, and employers and employees working in establishments with less than 10 persons engaged [45].
A sampling frame of all informal sector workers in Wuhan did not exist because many of the rural-to-urban migrants in Wuhan are not officially registered. We defined migrants as survey participants who stated that their household registration (hukou) was not in Wuhan City. In order to select a representative sample of informal sector workers, we chose a two-stage cluster sampling scheme. Our primary sampling units were sides of city blocks during one of two six hour time intervals (8:00 am to 2:00 pm and 2:00 pm to 8:00 pm), i.e. there were four primary sampling units per city block. In the first sampling stage, we randomly selected 60 primary sampling units using a list of city blocks published by the City Government of Wuhan. One hour before the start of the selected time interval, the interviewers went to the selected side of the city block and drew a map of the people working on the pavement, on the street, or inside the houses, huts or other constructions facing the street (see Figure 2 for an illustration). People who were moving through the street block and customers were not mapped. The people on the map were then enumerated. In order to achieve a self-weighting sampling scheme, in the second sampling stage an equal proportion (5%) of the mapped individuals in each primary sampling unit were randomly selected and asked for their consent to participate in the study [46].
We used estimates of the distribution of cluster sizes and the average intraclass correlation coefficient from the pilot to calculate the design effect due to clustering, using an approximation proposed by Holt [47]. We adjusted the sample size that would be needed to measure WTP with the desired precision (95% confidence interval (CI) with a margin of error of 5 RMB), if a simple random sample were drawn, in order to take into account clustering (using the estimated design effect) and refusals. The number of clusters (60) was chosen for operational reasons. The final sample size was 651.

Questionnaire

The questionnaire had three parts. First, the interviewers described the purpose of the study and asked respondents whether they consented to participate. Second, the interviewers asked participants questions about a number of individual characteristics. Neither participants' names nor any other characteristics that would allow identification of the participants after the interview were elicited or recorded. Third, the interviewers described the basic health insurance to the study participants. The description included the BHI benefits (hospital, outpatient and emergency care), the deductible, coinsurance and reimbursement ceiling (including a picture depicting how different copayments affect coverage), as well as the payment vehicle for premium contributions (a monthly premium paid into a city-wide social risk pooling fund managed by the Wuhan Bureau for Social Security). The benefits as well as copayments were in line with the 1999 central government provisions about the BHI and decisions by the provincial government of Hubei Province [48, 49] and were implemented in 1999 in at least one city in Hubei Province (Yichang) [50]. The deductible was 9% of the average annual salary of formal sector workers in the jurisdiction or 700 RMB; the coinsurance was 10% for inpatient services, 20% for special procedures such as diagnostic imaging, cancer chemotherapy and dialysis, and 30% for outpatient services; the reimbursement ceiling was 4 times the average annual salary of formal sector workers or 30,000 RMB. Respondents were asked about their maximum WTP for baseline BHI and, separately, its three variations (i.e. BHI without ceiling, without deductible, and without coinsurance).
The central government proposal specifies that the BHI should be administered at the city level. In addition to payments into a city-wide social risk pooling fund the BHI for formal sector workers also includes medical savings accounts (MSA). Money that accrues in the MSA is reserved to pay for health expenditure. Funds in the MSA that are unspent at the end of a person's life are inheritable [51]. We did not include MSA in the specification of the payment vehicle in the WTP question, because it would have made the valuation more difficult to understand and the WTP responses more difficult to interpret (as respondents may value MSAs not only as a form of health insurance but also as a form of life insurance). Further, it is unclear whether or not the BHI for informal sector workers should include MSA.

Demand curve fitting

Fitting demand curves from WTP data requires the selection of a functional form. We used the following criteria in the selection. First, at a premium contribution of zero all respondents should be willing to obtain the BHI. Second, the demand for BHI should (asymptotically) reach zero. Third, all else equal a simpler functional form should be preferred over a more complicated one. Fourth, the functional form should fit the WTP data better than other functional forms that satisfy the first three criteria [52]. Experimentation revealed that the simple exponential model Q = 100eb*WTP where Q = proportion of the sample willing to pay at least the WTP amount, WTP, satisfied all four criteria. We estimated the exponential model iteratively by least squares regression.

Equity weighting

In order to evaluate the social benefit of the BHI for informal sector workers, the individual WTP values need to be aggregated. One way to aggregate individual WTP is to sum up the WTP values as they are stated by the respondents, i.e. give everybody's WTP equal weight. However, WTP is a function of ability to pay. Weighting everybody's WTP equally will only then lead to results that can be considered fair if either the current income distribution is fair or all individuals have identical, linear utility functions. It is unlikely that the current income distribution in China is considered fair. For instance, the Chinese government is currently implementing large anti-poverty programmes in rural and urban China [53]. There is little empirical support for linear utility functions [54].
In order to derive a weighting scheme that takes account of equity concerns in the best possible way (i.e. maximizes social welfare) one needs to assume specific functional forms for individuals' utility functions and the social welfare function to be used to aggregate individual utilities. The choice of the utility function is a matter of empirical evidence; the choice of the social welfare function involves a value judgment about society's view on equity. We assumed that individuals' utility functions are identical and isoelastic (i.e. income elasticity of marginal utility is constant)
u i = y i ( 1 e ) ( 1 e ) MathType@MTEF@5@5@+=feaafiart1ev1aaatCvAUfKttLearuWrP9MDH5MBPbIqV92AaeXatLxBI9gBaebbnrfifHhDYfgasaacH8akY=wiFfYdH8Gipec8Eeeu0xXdbba9frFj0=OqFfea0dXdd9vqai=hGuQ8kuc9pgc9s8qqaq=dirpe0xb9q8qiLsFr0=vr0=vr0dc8meaabaqaciaacaGaaeqabaqabeGadaaakeaacqWG1bqDdaWgaaWcbaGaemyAaKgabeaakiabg2da9maalaaabaGaemyEaK3aa0baaSqaaiabdMgaPbqaaiabcIcaOiabigdaXiabgkHiTiabdwgaLjabcMcaPaaaaOqaaiabcIcaOiabigdaXiabgkHiTiabdwgaLjabcMcaPaaaaaa@3D97@
where ui= individual i's utility; yi= income; e = income elasticity of marginal utility or 'inequality aversion parameter'
and that the social welfare function is utilitarian, i.e. every person's utility receives equal weight in the aggregation of utililities across individuals
S W = i = 1 n u i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+=feaafiart1ev1aaatCvAUfKttLearuWrP9MDH5MBPbIqV92AaeXatLxBI9gBaebbnrfifHhDYfgasaacH8akY=wiFfYdH8Gipec8Eeeu0xXdbba9frFj0=OqFfea0dXdd9vqai=hGuQ8kuc9pgc9s8qqaq=dirpe0xb9q8qiLsFr0=vr0=vr0dc8meaabaqaciaacaGaaeqabaqabeGadaaakeaacqWGtbWucqWGxbWvcqGH9aqpdaaeWbqaaiabdwha1naaBaaaleaacqWGPbqAaeqaaaqaaiabdMgaPjabg2da9iabigdaXaqaaiabd6gaUbqdcqGHris5aaaa@39FF@
where SW = social welfare.
It can be easily shown that social welfare will be maximized if individual WTP, WTPi, are aggregated according to the following weighting scheme
i = 1 n ( y ¯ y i ) e W T P i MathType@MTEF@5@5@+=feaafiart1ev1aaatCvAUfKttLearuWrP9MDH5MBPbIqV92AaeXatLxBI9gBaebbnrfifHhDYfgasaacH8akY=wiFfYdH8Gipec8Eeeu0xXdbba9frFj0=OqFfea0dXdd9vqai=hGuQ8kuc9pgc9s8qqaq=dirpe0xb9q8qiLsFr0=vr0=vr0dc8meaabaqaciaacaGaaeqabaqabeGadaaakeaadaaeWbqaamaabmaabaWaaSaaaeaacuWG5bqEgaqeaaqaaiabdMha5naaBaaaleaacqWGPbqAaeqaaaaaaOGaayjkaiaawMcaamaaCaaaleqabaGaemyzaugaaOGaem4vaCLaemivaqLaemiuaa1aaSbaaSqaaiabdMgaPbqabaaabaGaemyAaKMaeyypa0JaeGymaedabaGaemOBa4ganiabggHiLdaaaa@4073@
where y ¯ MathType@MTEF@5@5@+=feaafiart1ev1aaatCvAUfKttLearuWrP9MDH5MBPbIqV92AaeXatLxBI9gBaebbnrfifHhDYfgasaacH8akY=wiFfYdH8Gipec8Eeeu0xXdbba9frFj0=OqFfea0dXdd9vqai=hGuQ8kuc9pgc9s8qqaq=dirpe0xb9q8qiLsFr0=vr0=vr0dc8meaabaqaciaacaGaaeqabaqabeGadaaakeaacuWG5bqEgaqeaaaa@2E3F@ = average income,
i.e. the WTPs of workers with below average income are given weights greater than one and the WTPs of workers with above average income are given weights less than one [54]. The larger is the inequality aversion parameter e, the more averse to income inequality is a society. Such an equity weighting has been proposed for use in applied cost-benefit analysis [55, 56]. While there is no published study about the shape of the marginal utility of income function in China, there is empirical evidence from India [55, 57] and developed countries [55, 5860] that the marginal utility of income is indeed constant. Most empirical studies have found values of e between 1.0 and 2.0 [58, 61]. We thus used three different values of e in our calculations: 0.5, 1.5 and 2.0. Because the BHI pools health risks at the city level [6], we used the average income in Wuhan in 2001 as an estimate of y ¯ MathType@MTEF@5@5@+=feaafiart1ev1aaatCvAUfKttLearuWrP9MDH5MBPbIqV92AaeXatLxBI9gBaebbnrfifHhDYfgasaacH8akY=wiFfYdH8Gipec8Eeeu0xXdbba9frFj0=OqFfea0dXdd9vqai=hGuQ8kuc9pgc9s8qqaq=dirpe0xb9q8qiLsFr0=vr0=vr0dc8meaabaqaciaacaGaaeqabaqabeGadaaakeaacuWG5bqEgaqeaaaa@2E3F@ .

Independent variables

We collected information on individual characteristics that were hypothesized to be determinants or correlates of WTP for health insurance as independent variables in multiple regression analysis [39]. We expected WTP to increase with age (because morbidity increases with age), income (because, holding other factors constant, higher income should lead to higher demand of all goods that are not inferior goods and there is no evidence to suggest that health insurance is an inferior good), and education (because individuals who have a low time preference should be both more likely to invest in education and more willing to pay for insurance).
In addition, we asked participants about their migration status, employment status, and health expenditure in the past year. We hypothesized that migrants have a lower WTP for BHI than Wuhan residents, because they are more likely than residents to leave Wuhan in the future and the BHI reimburses health expenditure only if it accrues in Wuhan. We further expected that, after controlling for income, permanently employed workers have a higher WTP for health insurance than workers who are only temporarily employed. The BHI guarantees coverage only if all monthly contributions have been paid up to the point in time when health expenditure accrues. Net of other factors, workers who are in temporary employment should be more likely than workers in permanent employment to default on their payments for the BHI in the future and thus have lower WTP for BHI in the present. Furthermore, respondents who have incurred higher health expenditure in the recent past are likely less healthy than those with lower past health expenditure and should thus be expected to be willing to pay more for participation in the BHI. Finally, we included sex as an independent variable because other studies have found significantly higher or lower WTP for health insurance among women than among men [25, 30, 31, 34] (possibly, because gender roles influence health care-seeking behaviour and health insurance decisions). We logarithmically transformed the income variable and the health expenditure variable in order to reduce skewness in their distributions. See Table 1 for the definitions, means and standard deviations of the independent variables.
Table 1
Independent variables (N = 609)
Variable name
Definition
Mean
SD
AGE
Age in years
35.6
10.8
MALE
Dummy variable = 1 if sex is male, 0 if female
0.49
0.50
EDU2
Dummy variable = 1 if highest educational attainment above elementary school but not above middle school, 0 otherwise
0.35
0.48
EDU3
Dummy variable = 1 if highest educational attainment above middle school but not above high school, 0 otherwise
0.39
0.49
EDU4
Dummy variable = 1 if highest educational attainment above high school, 0 otherwise
0.11
0.31
INCOME
Monthly income (RMB)
874.8
760.2
MIGRANT
Dummy variable = 1 if migration status is migrant, 0 if resident
0.21
0.41
EMPLOY
Dummy variable = 1 if employment is permanent, 0 if employment is temporary
0.8
0.40
HEX
Average monthly health expenditure in the past year (RMB)
27.4
72.1
SD = standard deviation, RMB = Renminbi

Statistical analyses

On a payment card, the line of all positive WTP amounts is split into j mutually exclusive and exhaustive categories. The true WTP, WTP*, lies between the highest WTP value circled on the card, PCj, and the next highest value, PCj+1, where j = 0,..., J. When regressing such an interval-coded dependent variable against independent variables
https://static-content.springer.com/image/art%3A10.1186%2F1472-6963-7-114/MediaObjects/12913_2007_455_Eque_HTML.gif
the probability that WTP* falls in the jth category is given by
https://static-content.springer.com/image/art%3A10.1186%2F1472-6963-7-114/MediaObjects/12913_2007_455_Equf_HTML.gif
where F(·) is the standard normal cumulative distribution function evaluated at (·). The likelihood function is the product of these probabilities across the j categories and over the n observations
L = i = 0 n j = 0 J [ F ( P C j x i β / σ ) F ( P C j + 1 x i β / σ ) ] δ i j MathType@MTEF@5@5@+=feaafiart1ev1aaatCvAUfKttLearuWrP9MDH5MBPbIqV92AaeXatLxBI9gBaebbnrfifHhDYfgasaacH8akY=wiFfYdH8Gipec8Eeeu0xXdbba9frFj0=OqFfea0dXdd9vqai=hGuQ8kuc9pgc9s8qqaq=dirpe0xb9q8qiLsFr0=vr0=vr0dc8meaabaqaciaacaGaaeqabaqabeGadaaakeaacqWGmbatcqGH9aqpdaqeWbqaamaarahabaWaamWaaeaacqWGgbGrcqGGOaakcqWGqbaucqWGdbWqdaWgaaWcbaGaemOAaOgabeaakiabgkHiTGqadiab=Hha4naaBaaaleaacqWFPbqAaeqaaGGadOGae4NSdiMaei4la8ccciGae03WdmNaeiykaKIaeyOeI0IaemOrayKaeiikaGIaemiuaaLaem4qam0aaSbaaSqaaiabdQgaQjabgUcaRiabigdaXaqabaGccqGHsislcqWF4baEdaWgaaWcbaGae8xAaKgabeaakiab+j7aIjabc+caViab9n8aZjabcMcaPaGaay5waiaaw2faamaaCaaaleqabaGae0hTdq2aaSbaaWqaaiabdMgaPjabdQgaQbqabaaaaaWcbaGaemOAaOMaeyypa0JaeGimaadabaGaemOsaOeaniabg+GivdaaleaacqWGPbqAcqGH9aqpcqaIWaamaeaacqWGUbGBa0Gaey4dIunaaaa@6359@
where δij= 1 if the ith observation falls in the jth category and 0 otherwise. Estimation of the model based on maximum likelihood, so-called interval regression, produces consistent and asymptotically efficient coefficient estimates [62].
Interval regression has been specifically recommended as the most appropriate regression method for analyzing results from contingent valuation studies using the payment card elicitation method [63] and has been used in many applied contingent valuation studies (e.g. [64, 65]). As a robustness check we ran ordinary least squares regressions (OLS) using the midpoint of the reported WTP interval. Interval regression and OLS assume that the error term is normally distributed. Because the distribution of WTP is skewed, normality of the error terms was more closely approximated when WTP was logarithmically transformed. Hence we used the natural logarithm of WTP as our dependent variables (i.e. we logarithmically transformed the boundaries of the payment card intervals for interval regression and the midpoint of the payment card intervals for OLS regression). We estimated
https://static-content.springer.com/image/art%3A10.1186%2F1472-6963-7-114/MediaObjects/12913_2007_455_Equg_HTML.gif
We adjusted the standard errors of the means of the unweighted and equity weighted WTP values, as well as the standard errors of the regression coefficients for intraclass correlation due to the clustering of individuals in the primary sampling units [66]. All analyses were performed with Stata 9.0 (Stata Corporation, College Station, Texas, USA).

Results

Sample

Out of 651 people who were asked whether they would be willing to participate in the study 621 consented to participate. Among the 621 participants 65 (i.e. 10.5%) answered zero to all four WTP questions. 11 answers were classified as protest zeros because respondents stated that "the BHI will not cover what it promises to cover" or "government should provide free health care for all" or that they were "too busy to bother with such things". In addition to the 11 respondents who gave protest-zero responses, one respondent was dropped from further analyses because he did not respond to the WTP questions, leaving a final sample of 609 respondents for analysis. The exclusion of protest zeros, did not significantly change the mean WTP for any of the four BHIs. When respondents who gave either a protest-zero response or did not answer the WTP questions were counted as non-responders, the response rate was 93.5%.
79% of the 609 informal sector workers included in our final sample were residents in Wuhan, while 21% were migrants. 80% of the workers had permanent and 20% had temporary employment (Table 1). Among residents, 69% were self-employed, 27% were employees and 4% were employers in enterprises with less than 10 people engaged. Among migrants, 97% were self-employed and 3% were employed in an enterprise with less than 10 people engaged. At the time of the study, not one of the respondents had health insurance coverage.

WTP for different types of BHI

The mean WTPs for baseline BHI and its three variations are displayed in Table 2. The first row shows the unweighted values. On average, respondents were willing to pay significantly more for any of the three variants of BHI than for the baseline BHI (all p < 0.0001).
Table 2
Willingness to pay for basic health insurance (N = 609)
 
WTP for baseline BHI
WTP for BHI without ceiling
WTP for BHI without deductible
WTP for BHI without coinsurance
 
Mean
95% CI
Mean
95% CI
Mean
95% CI
Mean
95% CI
Non-equity weighted
30
27–33
51
46–56
43
37–49
47
40–54
Equity weighted
        
   e = 1.0
38
32–43
66
55–76
56
46–65
59
48–70
   e = 1.5
67
47–86
121
83–159
102
70–134
107
69–145
   e = 2.0
166
93–239
310
170–450
263
145–382
275
133–417
All WTP values in Renminbi. WTP = willingness to pay, BHI = basic health insurance, CI = confidence interval
In comparison to the baseline BHI, respondents were willing to pay 70% more for BHI without ceiling, 43% more for the BHI without deductible and 56% more for the BHI without coinsurance. Among the 609 respondents who gave valid answers to the four WTP questions only 9, 20 and 27 were willing to pay more for the baseline WTP than for the BHI without ceiling, the BHI without deductible, and the BHI without coinsurance, respectively. Mean WTP ranked as follows: WTP for BHI without ceiling > WTP for BHI without coinsurance > WTP for BHI without deductible > WTP for baseline BHI. However, the means of the WTP for BHI without ceiling, without deductible, and without coinsurance were not significantly different from each other at the 5% confidence level.
Respondents were willing to pay substantial proportions of their income for the different BHIs: 4.6% for the baseline BHI (95% CI, 4.1–5.1%); 7.8% for BHI without ceiling (95% CI, 7.0–8.8%); 6.8% for BHI without deductible (95% CI, 5.9–7.6%); and 6.9% for BHI without coinsurance (95% CI, 6.2–7.8%). Table 3 shows the mean WTP (and the 95% CI) for the baseline BHI and its three variations by age group, sex, educational attainment, income group, migration status, employment status, and past health expenditure.
Table 3
Willingness to pay for basic health insurance by respondents' characteristics
 
WTP for baseline BHI
WTP for BHI without ceiling
WTP for BHI without deductible
WTP for BHI without coinsurance
 
Mean
95% CI
Mean
95% CI
Mean
95% CI
Mean
95% CI
Age group (years)
        
   18–30
33
28–39
55
45–64
51
37–66
51
36–65
   31–40
31
26–35
53
45–61
42
36–48
47
39–55
   41–50
24
20–28
42
34–50
36
27–44
46
29–64
   51–60
26
19–33
45
34–57
34
25–42
39
29–50
Sex
        
   Female
33
29–38
55
47–64
50
39–61
55
42–67
   Male
26
23–29
46
41–51
37
33–41
40
35–45
Educational attainment
        
   Elementary school or below
20
15–24
32
25–39
25
20–31
29
22–35
   Above elementary school but not above middle school
27
23–31
46
39–53
39
33–45
42
34–50
   Above middle school but not above high school
34
29–39
57
48–66
52
38–65
56
41–71
   Above high school
39
30–48
70
55–86
53
43–64
60
44–75
Monthly income (RMB)
        
   0–499
15
12–19
26
20–32
23
17–28
22
17–27
   500–999
25
23–28
42
38–47
35
32–39
39
34–43
   1000 and above
53
44–61
91
75–106
80
58–102
88
63–114
Migration status
        
   Resident
32
28–35
53
48–59
45
38–53
51
42–59
   Migrant
23
19–27
41
33–48
35
29–41
34
28–41
Employment status
        
   Temporary employment
19
16–23
33
26–39
27
23–32
27
22–32
   Permanent employment
32
29–36
55
49–61
47
40–54
52
44–61
Average monthly health expenditure in the past year (RMB)
        
   0–99
29
26–32
48
43–53
42
36–48
45
38–52
   100 and above
45
34–57
92
70–115
64
49–80
83
58–108
WTP = willingness to pay, BHI = basic health insurance, CI = confidence interval, RMB = Renminbi

Demand curves

Table 4 presents the results of the nonlinear regressions of BHI coverage against WTP. The coefficients of determination indicate a near perfect fit. Figure 3 displays the estimated demand curves. Unlike the convention in economics, quantity (i.e. coverage) is displayed on the y-axis and price (i.e. WTP or maximum premium contribution) on the x-axis. At low levels of premium contribution, coverage declined rapidly with increasing contributions. For instance, 43% of the sample were willing to pay 20 RMB or more for the baseline BHI, but only 29% were willing to pay 30 RMB or more.
Table 4
Demand curve regressions
 
b
t ratio
p
Adj. R 2
Number of data points
Sample size
Coverage with baseline BHI
-0.0416
-51.77
< 0.0001
0.9987
16
609
Coverage with BHI without ceiling
-0.0235
-57.65
< 0.0001
0.9988
20
609
Coverage with BHI without deductible
-0.0285
-62.95
< 0.0001
0.9991
18
609
Coverage with BHI without coinsurance
-0.0284
-44.57
< 0.0001
0.9979
20
609
BHI = basic health insurance, b = regression coefficient

Equity weighted aggregation of individual WTP

The means of all equity weighted WTP were considerably higher than the means of the non-equity weighted WTP and increased with the inequality aversion parameter e. In comparison to the non-equity weighted WTPs, the mean WTPs were 1.3 times higher if e = 1.0; 2.3 to 2.4 times higher if e = 1.5; and 5.9 to 6.1 times higher if e = 2.0. The ranking of the point estimates of WTP for the different types of BHI was robust across all three equity weighting schemes (BHI without ceiling > BHI without coinsurance > BHI without deductible > baseline BHI) (Table 2). However, the only significant differences at the 5% confidence level between means of WTP for different types of BHI were found between WTP for baseline BHI and each of its three variations without equity weighting or with equity weighting and an inequality aversion parameter e of 1.0.

Comparison of WTP to estimates of the costs of BHI

This study did not include a bottom-up calculation of the costs of the BHI. We estimated BHI costs with two types of information. First, we approximated costs with the average premium contribution of a formal sector worker to the BHI. The baseline BHI for formal sector employees is stipulated to be financed by 4.2% of employees' pre-tax wages and the resulting contributions are expected to cover the costs of BHI [6]. The central government policy decrees that the employer contributes 6% and the employee contributes 2% of the employee's wage to the BHI system [6]. However, only 4.2% of the wages are used to finance the BHI as described in the WTP question in this study. The remaining 3.8% are saved in MSA [67]. Participants in the BHI can use the money in the MSA to pay for health care which is not reimbursed by the social risk pooling fund because of the deductible, coinsurance or ceiling of the BHI [6]. The benefits of the MSA were not included in the valuations of the baseline BHI in this study. In 2001, average annual pre-tax income in Wuhan was 7091 RMB [68]. The average monthly cost of BHI was thus estimated to be 24.8 RMB.
Second, we used the respondents' past health expenditure to approximate the costs of the BHI. Average monthly health expenditure in the past year was 27.4 RMB (95% CI 21.6–33.1) (see Table 1). If we applied a deductible of 700 RMB, average monthly health expenditure accruing to the BHI would be reduced to 18.1 RMB (95% CI 12.2–23.9). If we applied a coinsurance of 10% in addition to the deductible, average monthly expenditure would be further reduced (to 16.3 RMB). The mean non-equity weighted WTP for baseline BHI and all three equity weighted means of WTP for baseline BHI were significantly larger than the above cost estimates.

Determinants of willingness to pay

The explained variation of the multiple regression models was measured by McKelvey and Zavoina's R 2 in interval regressions and by the coefficient of determination, R 2, in OLS regressions [69]. It ranged from 21% to 28%. All models were statistically significant (all p < 0.0001). In all regressions the following factors significantly influenced WTP: age (AGE; p values between 0.0002 and 0.0356), sex (MALE; p values between 0.0003 and 0.0538), income (INCOME; all p < 0.0001), past health expenditure (HEX; p values between < 0.0001 and 0.0004) and employment status (EMPLOY; p values between 0.0009 and 0.0324) (Table 5). Migration status was significant at the 5% confidence level in predicting WTP for baseline BHI, WTP for BHI without ceiling, and WTP for BHI without coinsurance (MIGRANT; p values between 0.0001 and 0.0475) and borderline significant in predicting WTP for BHI without deductible (both p < 0.0800). The educational attainment variables (EDU2-4) were neither individually nor jointly significant in predicting WTP except for highest educational attainment above high school (EDU4), which significantly increased WTP in the models labelled 2.1, 3.1, 3.2 and 4.1 in Table 5.
Table 5
Determinants of willingness to pay
Dependent variables
WTP for baseline BHI (ln)
WTP for BHI without ceiling (ln)
WTP for BHI without deductible (ln)
WTP for BHI without coinsurance (ln)
Model
1.1
1.2
2.1
2.2
3.1
3.2
4.1
4.2
Regression
Interval regression
OLS
Interval regression
OLS
Interval regression
OLS
Interval regression
OLS
AGE
-0.013
-0.014
-0.014
-0.016
-0.014
-0.015
-0.010
-0.012
 
(0.0039)
(0.0043)
(0.0044)
(0.0048)
(0.0037)
(0.0041)
(0.0049)
(0.0052)
 
0.0010
0.0018
0.0013
0.0017
0.0002
0.0003
0.0356
0.0294
MALE
-0.203
-0.221
-0.154
-0.166
-0.198
-0.212
-0.212
-0.226
 
(0.0558)
(0.0635)
(0.0756)
(0.0843)
(0.0643)
(0.0721)
(0.0670)
(0.0745)
 
0.0003
0.0010
0.0416
0.0538
0.0020
0.0046
0.0016
0.0036
EDU2
0.140
0.148
0.156
0.154
0.219
0.227
0.151
0.150
 
(0.0978)
(0.1097)
(0.1260)
(0.1409)
(0.1126)
(0.1260)
(0.1076)
(0.1187)
 
0.1527
0.1825
0.2157
0.2786
0.0522
0.0764
0.1614
0.2099
EDU3
0.084
0.083
0.133
0.122
0.207
0.206
0.165
0.163
 
(0.1182)
(0.1311)
(0.1424)
(0.1579)
(0.1424)
(0.1575)
(0.1264)
(0.1390)
 
0.4761
0.5275
0.3515
0.4443
0.1461
0.1951
0.1913
0.2488
EDU4
0.222
0.230
0.333
0.334
0.347
0.356
0.305
0.302
 
(0.1527)
(0.1682)
(0.1645)
(0.1827)
(0.1561)
(0.1734)
(0.1470)
(0.1622)
 
0.1458
0.1768
0.0429
0.0724
0.0262
0.0447
0.0379
0.0676
INCOME (ln)
0.439
0.468
0.469
0.499
0.458
0.489
0.434
0.461
 
(0.0504)
(0.0542)
(0.0588)
(0.0642)
(0.0574)
(0.0622)
(0.0566)
(0.0613)
 
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
MIGRANT
-0.345
-0.373
-0.214
-0.224
-0.174
-0.187
-0.287
-0.303
 
(0.0888)
(0.1025)
(0.0979)
(0.1108)
(0.0915)
(0.1050)
(0.1033)
(0.1157)
 
0.0001
0.0006
0.0285
0.0475
0.0566
0.0800
0.0054
0.0113
EMPLOY
0.224
0.232
0.258
0.273
0.191
0.198
0.290
0.300
 
(0.0835)
(0.0910)
(0.0930)
(0.1022)
(0.0826)
(0.0905)
(0.0872)
(0.0962)
 
0.0073
0.0133
0.0055
0.0098
0.0209
0.0324
0.0009
0.0028
HEX (ln)
0.076
0.083
0.139
0.148
0.090
0.098
0.087
0.093
 
(0.0198)
(0.0210)
(0.0220)
(0.0234)
(0.0203)
(0.0216)
(0.0236)
(0.0248)
 
0.0001
0.0002
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
0.0002
0.0004
Constant
0.008
-0.266
0.204
-0.026
0.265
0.019
0.182
-0.035
 
(0.3315)
(0.3617)
(0.3853)
(0.4270)
(0.3893)
(0.4239)
(0.4001)
(0.4358)
 
0.9815
0.4642
0.5957
0.9508
0.4965
0.9643
0.6495
0.9363
N
609
609
609
609
609
609
609
609
F
 
22.7
 
23.1
 
21.7
 
19.11
Log likelihood
-1308
 
-1486
 
-1433
 
-1475
 
R 2
 
0.247
 
0.259
 
0.242
 
0.213
McKelvey and Zavoina's R 2
0.266
 
0.277
 
0.257
 
0.224
 
p value
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
< 0.0001
The numbers in the cells are regression coefficient, heteroscedasticity-robust standard error adjusted for clustering of the data in 60 primary sampling units (in brackets) and p value.
WTP = willingness to pay, BHI = basic health insurance, OLS = ordinary least squares regression, ln = natural logarithm
Since we used the natural logarithm of the four WTP as dependent variables, the coefficients in Table 5 are either semi-elasticities (if the independent variable is in natural units) or elasticities (if the independent variable is logarithmically transformed). An increase of one year in age decreased WTP by between 1.0% and 1.6%. Net of the other factors included in the regression models, men had lower WTP than women (between 15.4% and 22.6% lower), migrants had lower WTP than residents (between 17.4% and 37.3% lower), and informal workers in permanent employment had higher WTP than workers in temporary employment (between 19.1% and 30.0% higher). A 1% increase in monthly income increased WTP by between 0.434% and 0.499% and 1% increase in health expenditure in the past year increased WTP by between 0.076% and 0.148% (Table 5).
The regression results were largely unaffected by the choice of regression model. The coefficient sizes and the significance levels in the OLS regression models were similar to those in the interval regression models. Only two coefficients differed by more than 10%. The age coefficients in the OLS regression models labelled 2.2 and 4.2 in Table 5 were respectively 14% and 20% lower than the age coefficients in the corresponding interval regressions (models 2.1 and 4.1 in Table 5).

Discussion

Validity of WTP

Most informal sector workers in Wuhan are currently not eligible to participate in the BHI (see below). If the City Government of Wuhan decides to open the BHI to a broad range of informal sector workers, this study will offer a rare opportunity to assess the criterion validity of WTP responses by comparing actual demand to demand predicted from a contingent valuation study. For now, we can only examine the construct validity of the WTP responses, i.e. investigate whether WTP relates to certain constructs as predicted by theory. Two commonly used tests of construct validity of WTP are the income elasticity test and the scope test [70]. With the rare exception of inferior goods, demand theory predicts that income elasticity of goods is positive and there is no evidence to suggest that health insurance is an inferior good. We found that the income elasticity of BHI is indeed positive after controlling for sex, age, migration status, employment status and health expenditure. Our results thus pass the income elasticity test.
The scope test assesses whether WTP increases as more of a good is supplied [71, 72]. We found that mean WTP significantly increases and that the demand curve is shifted upward as the scope of the BHI increases, i.e. as either the reimbursement ceiling, the deductible or the coinsurance are removed from the baseline BHI. A few respondents were willing to pay less for one of the variants of BHI than for the baseline BHI. However, this does not imply that the answers of these respondents are invalid. While the removal of the ceiling, the deductible or the coinsurance never decreases the scope of the BHI, respondents may truly value the BHI variants less than the baseline BHI because they associate other changes in the BHI with the change in scope. For instance, a respondent may expect that the BHI without coinsurance will be less sustainable than the BHI with coinsurance and thus value the former less than the latter.
Weaker tests of construct validity of WTP responses include assessments of the relationship between respondents' characteristics other than income. All our independent variables influenced WTP for BHI as hypothesized, with two exceptions. First, WTP decreases significantly with age. We had hypothesized that WTP for health insurance would be a positive function of age because the risk of disease increases with age. However, it is plausible that age not only proxies for disease risk but is also associated with factors that are not controlled for in our regression analyses and are negatively associated with WTP for BHI. Younger informal sector workers may be more likely than older workers to be employed in occupations that carry a high risk of accidents, for instance in construction. Also, the age variable may capture cohort effects. For instance, older informal sector workers may believe that their children will finance their health care should they become ill, while younger workers do not.
Second, the relationship between education and WTP was not very strong. We had hypothesized that higher education leads to higher WTP for BHI, because people who discount the future at a lower rate both invest more in their education and are willing to pay more in order to insure against future health expenditure. However, it seems plausible that educational attainment in China has in the past not been determined by preferences but by factors such as place of birth, party affiliation or early educational performance. Overall, tests of construct validity suggest that the results of our contingent valuation study are valid.

Policy relevance

Health policy in China is formulated centrally, but decentralization has given lower levels of government power to adapt policies from higher levels to local circumstances, leading to a situation where "governments at all levels are both policy-makers and policy-implementers" [9]. Discrepancies between central policy directives and local policy implementation have been observed for several health policies in China, such as disease control policies [73] and health care price setting [74].
The introduction of the BHI in Chinese cities is an example of the simultaneity of policy formulation and implementation at the local level. While the 1998 central government policy includes detailed directives about the attributes of the BHI (e.g. the proportions of a formal sector worker's salary that employer and employee need to contribute to the BHI) [6], some municipal governments have implemented modified versions of the BHI, for instance in Shanghai and Beijing [75, 76]. Municipal governments have even more discretion in making decisions about expanding BHI to informal sector workers. The 1998 central government policy allows such an expansion, but does not require it. Recently, however, different levels of the Chinese government within and outside the health sector have called for improved social protection, including health insurance, for urban informal sector workers [20, 7779].
In 2004, the City Government of Wuhan issued the Wuhan City regulation about basic health insurance for urban informal sector workers. The regulation defines the eligibility criteria for participation in the BHI such that most informal workers are, in fact, barred from joining [80]. First, only those informal sector workers who have a permanent household registration (hukou) in Wuhan can join, which excludes migrant workers from participation. Second, men can only join if they have been enrolled in the state-run old-age pension scheme for at least 30 years and women can only join if they have been enrolled for at least 25 years. Since only formal sector workers are entitled to participate in the state-run old-age pension scheme, this second condition effectively prevents all informal sector workers from participating in the BHI who have never worked in the formal sector. Moreover, it excludes all men who were laid-off after less than 30 years of formal sector work and all women who were laid-off after less than 25 years from joining the BHI. Third, men younger than 16 or older than 60 years of age and women younger than 16 or older than 55 years of age are not eligible to participate in the BHI. The upper age limits prevent many of those few former formal sector workers who have been working long enough in the formal sector to meet the second eligibility criterion from participating in the BHI, because they are too old.
A few cities in China allow broader categories of informal sector workers to participate in the BHI if they contribute the same proportion of their incomes as formal sector workers or pay premiums similar to the average absolute premium paid by formal workers [77, 81, 82]. However, participation in these voluntary BHI schemes has been low [82]. Workers in the formal sector pay only a part of the total contribution directly from their salaries, while their employers pay the remainder. In contrast, informal sector workers usually have to pay the total contribution from their own incomes because they are either self-employed or employed in small-scale enterprises that do not contribute to their employees' insurance coverage [83].
This is the first study to investigate WTP to participate in social health insurance among informal sector workers in a large Chinese city. Many factors, such as political will and financial, managerial and technical resources, will influence municipal governments' decisions to offer informal sector workers participation in the BHI. Our study may support the decision making by providing evidence about the social desirability of the BHI, preferences for BHI attributes, and characteristics of informal sector workers that influence the valuation of BHI.
On average, informal workers are willing to pay substantial absolute amounts and substantial proportions of their incomes to obtain social health insurance coverage. We find that average WTP is significantly higher than estimates of average cost of BHI based on the premium contributions of formal sector workers and past health expenditure of informal sector workers. From a normative perspective, the provision of the BHI to informal sector workers should thus increase social welfare.
Whether the net benefits of the BHI will be positive or not depends on the validity of our cost estimates. For our first cost estimate – the average premium contribution of formal sector workers – to accurately represent the average cost of BHI, the contribution rates that are stipulated in the 1998 central government policy need to be sufficiently high, so that the total premium contributions to the BHI cover total costs. The fact that in their implementation of the BHI for formal sector workers some cities have chosen contribution rates that are higher than the rates stipulated by the central government suggests that this assumption may not hold true [67]. For instance, in Shanghai employers are required to contribute 10% of an employee's annual wage to the BHI, while employees contribute 2% [75]. Even if the stipulated rates did lead to contributions that are sufficient to cover the costs of BHI for formal sector workers, they might not lead to contributions sufficient to cover the costs of BHI for informal sector workers, for instance because the latter face higher risks of work-related injuries and diseases than the former [82].
For our second cost estimate – the informal sector workers' past health expenditure, to approximate well the cost of BHI – the demand for health care must not be affected by insurance. However, insurance is likely to change the demand for health care because it decreases the price of health care (as well as workers' disposable incomes), and may lead to increased moral hazard behaviours.
While our cost estimates may thus be too low, the estimates of the benefits of BHI that do not take into account aversion to income inequality may underestimate the true size of the benefits from BHI. The equity weighted mean WTPs for BHI are much higher than non-equity weighted mean WTPs. If we assume, for instance, that the correct inequality aversion parameter for China is 1.5, the benefits of the BHI will be more than twice as high as the unweighted benefit estimates, so that net social benefit will be positive, unless costs have been underestimated by more than a factor 2. One indication that Chinese society is indeed inequality averse is that Chinese policy makers have stipulated that formal sector workers should contribute an equal proportion of their incomes to the BHI, i.e. to receive BHI coverage workers with higher incomes are required to pay larger absolute amounts into the social risk pooling fund than workers with lower incomes.
From a behavioural perspective, our result that coverage declines steeply with increasing premium contributions at low contribution levels suggests that government subsidies would be an effective mechanism to increase coverage with BHI among informal sector workers. Our results further suggest that informal sector workers do not value the BHI as a mechanism to recover the relatively frequent but small financial losses associated with common illnesses but because it protects against the rare but large financial losses associated with catastrophic care. The informal sector workers in our sample state a WTP that is on average higher than their health expenditure in the past year. In fact, only 62 of the 609 respondents would have received any money from the BHI at the level of their past year's health care spending; all other workers spent less on health care than the deductible. Nevertheless most workers are willing to pay positive amounts for the BHI, suggesting that workers value the protection against rare diseases that are expensive to treat. This conclusion is strengthened by our finding that average WTP for BHI increases significantly when the ceiling on coverage is removed, even though not one of the informal sector workers in our sample had health expenditure exceeding the ceiling in the past year.
A recent study investigated WTP for private health insurance in four small cities in China's Shandong and Sichuan Provinces [35]. As described above, this study differs from ours in important aspects, including the target population, the type of insurance and the setting. Nevertheless, it is interesting that the study finds that respondents value insurance for catastrophic diseases (such as cancer and end-stage renal disease) and inpatient care more highly than insurance for outpatient care. This reinforces our finding that people in urban China value financial protection against catastrophic care expenditure more highly than recovery of costs of treating minor diseases.
Our results suggest three potential limitations of a voluntary BHI for informal sector workers. First, voluntary BHI for informal sector workers may suffer from some adverse selection. We find that WTP increases significantly with health expenditure in the past year. As past health expenditure proxies future health expenditure [84] at any given premium contribution those who take out the BHI would be expected to incur higher health expenditure than those who do not. However, while past health expenditure significantly increases WTP, the effect is not very large. A 10% increase in past health expenditure leads to 0.76% increase in WTP for baseline BHI and to a 1.39% increase in WTP for BHI without ceiling. In comparison, a 10% increase in income will lead to a 4.39% increase in WTP for baseline BHI and a 4.69% increase in WTP for BHI without ceiling.
Second, large proportions of informal sector workers will choose not to buy the BHI at relatively low contribution levels. At a price of 25 RMB per month (i.e. our estimate of average monthly costs of the BHI based on the contributions of formal sector workers) 35% of informal sector workers will buy the BHI. At a price of 20 RMB coverage of informal sector workers will increase to 43%.
In order to increase coverage, policy makers should consider changing the attributes of the BHI. According to our results, at any given premium contribution the coverage that will be achieved if informal sector workers were offered the BHI without ceiling, without deductible or without coinsurance will be higher than the coverage that can be achieved if they are offered the baseline BHI. While the average WTP for BHI without ceiling is not significantly higher than the average WTP for BHI without deductible or coinsurance, almost all respondents ranked the BHI without ceiling highest (by the WTP criterion) among the four different types of BHI offered. Including catastrophic care cover in the BHI would have the additional advantage of improving the effectiveness of the BHI in ensuring access to needed health care and averting poverty, while removing the deductible or the coinsurance may come with the disadvantage of increasing consumer moral hazard. Our findings suggest that even if the government decides neither to subsidise nor change the BHI, coverage will increase over time as the Chinese economy continues to grow (because WTP for BHI increases significantly with income).
Third, at any given premium the most vulnerable informal workers will be least likely to buy the BHI. Holding other factors equal, workers who do not buy the BHI will on average be older, poorer, and more likely to be migrants and without permanent employment than workers who do buy the BHI. In order to increase coverage amongst the most vulnerable workers, policy makers may consider a number of means, including targeted public marketing campaigns, specific subsidies (for instance for older workers) or changes to the BHI that specifically increase the attractiveness of the BHI for vulnerable workers (for instance, portability of the BHI may increase coverage amongst migrants).

Conclusion

Our results suggest that Chinese municipal governments should allow informal sector workers to participate in the BHI. From a normative perspective, BHI for informal sector workers is likely to increase social welfare. The increases in social welfare are likely to be larger if Chinese society is averse to income inequality. Our results further suggest that informal sector workers do not value the BHI as a mechanism to recover the relatively frequent but small financial losses associated with common illnesses, but because it protects against the rare but large financial losses associated with catastrophic care.
From a behavioural perspective, at a price level equal to the average premium contribution of formal sector workers 35% of informal workers should be expected to enrol in the BHI. Because coverage declines steeply with increasing premium contributions at low contribution levels, subsidies could be an effective means to increase coverage. According to our results, modifications of the copayment structure of the BHI, such as eliminating the reimbursement ceiling, or changes in other attributes, such as including portability, could increase population coverage. Moreover, coverage should expand as the Chinese economy continues to grow. Finally, adverse selection will be unlikely to be a large problem if the BHI is offered to informal sector workers.

Acknowledgements

We want to thank Prof. Xinzheng Jin at the Centre for Health Care Administration, Huazhong University of Technology and Science, Wuhan, China, for support in organizing the fieldwork for this study, the graduate students at the Centre for Health Care Administration who conducted the study interviews for their excellent work, and Prof. Yufeng Ding at Tongji Medical College, Huazhong University of Science and Technology, for providing us with some of the background information used in this article.
We would further like to thank Prof. William C. Hsiao, Prof. Winnie Yip and other participants of a lunch seminar on Chinese health care reform at Harvard University in January 2007 for their helpful comments on an earlier version of this manuscript. During the time of the study, Till Bärnighausen was supported by a post-doctoral fellowship grant from the German Academic Exchange Service (DAAD) (Joint International Research Programme of the Federal Government and the Governments of the States).
This article is published under license to BioMed Central Ltd. This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​2.​0), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

Competing interests

The author(s) declare that they have no competing interests.

Authors' contributions

TB, XZ RS designed the study. TB and XZ carried out the pilot survey and the main survey. TB performed the statistical analysis and drafted the manuscript. YL, XZ and RS were involved in the interpretation of the data and revised the manuscript critically for important intellectual content. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.
Anhänge

Authors’ original submitted files for images

Literatur
1.
Zurück zum Zitat Liu XZ, Wang JL: An introduction to China's health care system. J Public Health Policy. 1991, 12: 104-116. 10.2307/3342782.PubMedCrossRef Liu XZ, Wang JL: An introduction to China's health care system. J Public Health Policy. 1991, 12: 104-116. 10.2307/3342782.PubMedCrossRef
2.
Zurück zum Zitat Wang P, Zhang Z, Zheng D: The organisation of the Chinese social security system – 20 years. 1998, Beijing, Middle District Publishing Company for Classic Texts Wang P, Zhang Z, Zheng D: The organisation of the Chinese social security system – 20 years. 1998, Beijing, Middle District Publishing Company for Classic Texts
3.
Zurück zum Zitat Shen HL: The health care system in urban China. 1995, Beijing, Chinese Publishing Company for Health and Pharmaceutical Science and Technology Shen HL: The health care system in urban China. 1995, Beijing, Chinese Publishing Company for Health and Pharmaceutical Science and Technology
4.
Zurück zum Zitat Hu T, Ong M, Lin Z, Li E: The effects of economic reform on health insurance and the financial burden for urban workers in China. Health Econ. 1999, 8: 309-321. 10.1002/(SICI)1099-1050(199906)8:4<309::AID-HEC440>3.0.CO;2-N.PubMedCrossRef Hu T, Ong M, Lin Z, Li E: The effects of economic reform on health insurance and the financial burden for urban workers in China. Health Econ. 1999, 8: 309-321. 10.1002/(SICI)1099-1050(199906)8:4<309::AID-HEC440>3.0.CO;2-N.PubMedCrossRef
5.
Zurück zum Zitat Liu GG, Zhao Z, Cai R, Yamada T, Yamada T: Equity in health care access to: assessing the urban health insurance reform in China. Soc Sci Med. 2002, 55: 1779-1794. 10.1016/S0277-9536(01)00306-9.PubMedCrossRef Liu GG, Zhao Z, Cai R, Yamada T, Yamada T: Equity in health care access to: assessing the urban health insurance reform in China. Soc Sci Med. 2002, 55: 1779-1794. 10.1016/S0277-9536(01)00306-9.PubMedCrossRef
6.
Zurück zum Zitat Liu Y: Reforming China's urban health insurance system. Health Policy. 2002, 60: 133-150. 10.1016/S0168-8510(01)00207-X.PubMedCrossRef Liu Y: Reforming China's urban health insurance system. Health Policy. 2002, 60: 133-150. 10.1016/S0168-8510(01)00207-X.PubMedCrossRef
7.
Zurück zum Zitat Anonymous: The State Council resolution on building a basic health insurance system for urban employees and workers. Chinese Journal of Health Care Quality Management. 1998, 3: 5-6. Anonymous: The State Council resolution on building a basic health insurance system for urban employees and workers. Chinese Journal of Health Care Quality Management. 1998, 3: 5-6.
8.
Zurück zum Zitat State Council: Resolution on building a basic health insurance system for urban employees and workers. High Level Discussion Conference on Chinese Health Care Reform, 14 December 1998. 1998, Beijing State Council: Resolution on building a basic health insurance system for urban employees and workers. High Level Discussion Conference on Chinese Health Care Reform, 14 December 1998. 1998, Beijing
9.
Zurück zum Zitat World Health Organization: Health policy and systems research in China. 2004, Geneva, World Health Organization World Health Organization: Health policy and systems research in China. 2004, Geneva, World Health Organization
10.
Zurück zum Zitat Ministry of Health Centre for Health Statistics and Information: Preliminary report on the results of the 2003 National Health Services Survey. 2004, Beijing, Ministry of Health Ministry of Health Centre for Health Statistics and Information: Preliminary report on the results of the 2003 National Health Services Survey. 2004, Beijing, Ministry of Health
11.
Zurück zum Zitat Xu L, Wang Y, Collins CD, Tang S: Urban health insurance reform and coverage in China using data from National Health Services Surveys in 1998 and 2003. BMC Health Serv Res. 2007, 7: 37-10.1186/1472-6963-7-37.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef Xu L, Wang Y, Collins CD, Tang S: Urban health insurance reform and coverage in China using data from National Health Services Surveys in 1998 and 2003. BMC Health Serv Res. 2007, 7: 37-10.1186/1472-6963-7-37.PubMedPubMedCentralCrossRef
12.
Zurück zum Zitat Ghose AK: Employment in China: recent trends and future challenges. Employment Strategy Papers 2005/14. 2005, Geneva, International Labour Office Ghose AK: Employment in China: recent trends and future challenges. Employment Strategy Papers 2005/14. 2005, Geneva, International Labour Office
13.
Zurück zum Zitat Felipe J, Hasan R: The challenge of job creation in Asia. ERD Policy Brief Series 44. 2006, Manila, Philippines, Asian Development Bank Felipe J, Hasan R: The challenge of job creation in Asia. ERD Policy Brief Series 44. 2006, Manila, Philippines, Asian Development Bank
14.
Zurück zum Zitat Liu Y: What is wrong with China's health system?. Harvard China Rev (in print). 2006 Liu Y: What is wrong with China's health system?. Harvard China Rev (in print). 2006
15.
Zurück zum Zitat Ministry of Health Centre for Health Statistics and Information: Report on the results of the 1998 National Health Services Survey. 1999, Beijing, Ministry of Health Ministry of Health Centre for Health Statistics and Information: Report on the results of the 1998 National Health Services Survey. 1999, Beijing, Ministry of Health
16.
Zurück zum Zitat Liu Y, Rao K, Hsiao WC: Medical expenditure and rural impoverishment in China. J Health Popul and Nutr. 2003, 21: 216-222. Liu Y, Rao K, Hsiao WC: Medical expenditure and rural impoverishment in China. J Health Popul and Nutr. 2003, 21: 216-222.
17.
Zurück zum Zitat van Doorslaer E, O'Donnell O, Rannan-Eliya RP, Somanathan A, Adhikari SR, Garg CC, Harbianto D, Herrin AN, Huq MN, Ibragimova S, Karan A, Ng CW, Pande BR, Racelis R, Tao S, Tin K, Tisayaticom K, Trisnantoro L, Vasavid C, Zhao Y: Effect of payments for health care on poverty estimates in 11 countries in Asia: an analysis of household survey data. Lancet. 2006, 368: 1357-1364.PubMedCrossRef van Doorslaer E, O'Donnell O, Rannan-Eliya RP, Somanathan A, Adhikari SR, Garg CC, Harbianto D, Herrin AN, Huq MN, Ibragimova S, Karan A, Ng CW, Pande BR, Racelis R, Tao S, Tin K, Tisayaticom K, Trisnantoro L, Vasavid C, Zhao Y: Effect of payments for health care on poverty estimates in 11 countries in Asia: an analysis of household survey data. Lancet. 2006, 368: 1357-1364.PubMedCrossRef
18.
Zurück zum Zitat Ducket J: State, collectivism and worker privilege: a study of urban health insurance reform. China Quart. 2004, 177: 155-173. 10.1017/S0305741004000098.CrossRef Ducket J: State, collectivism and worker privilege: a study of urban health insurance reform. China Quart. 2004, 177: 155-173. 10.1017/S0305741004000098.CrossRef
19.
Zurück zum Zitat Yusuf S, Nabeshima K: China's development priorities. 2006, Washington, DC, The World BankCrossRef Yusuf S, Nabeshima K: China's development priorities. 2006, Washington, DC, The World BankCrossRef
20.
Zurück zum Zitat United Nations Development Programme (UNDP): China human development report 2005. 2005, New York, United NationsCrossRef United Nations Development Programme (UNDP): China human development report 2005. 2005, New York, United NationsCrossRef
21.
Zurück zum Zitat Gafni A: Willingness to pay: what's in a name. Pharmacoeconomics. 1998, 14: 465-470. 10.2165/00019053-199814050-00001.PubMedCrossRef Gafni A: Willingness to pay: what's in a name. Pharmacoeconomics. 1998, 14: 465-470. 10.2165/00019053-199814050-00001.PubMedCrossRef
22.
Zurück zum Zitat Mitchell R, Carson R: A contingent valuation estimate of national freshwater benefits: technical report to the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 1984, Washington, DC, Resources for the Future Mitchell R, Carson R: A contingent valuation estimate of national freshwater benefits: technical report to the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 1984, Washington, DC, Resources for the Future
23.
Zurück zum Zitat Bateman I, Langford I, Munro A, Starner C, Sugden R: Estimating four Hicksian welfare measures for a public good: a contingent valuation investigation. Land Econ. 2000, 76: 355-373. 10.2307/3147034.CrossRef Bateman I, Langford I, Munro A, Starner C, Sugden R: Estimating four Hicksian welfare measures for a public good: a contingent valuation investigation. Land Econ. 2000, 76: 355-373. 10.2307/3147034.CrossRef
24.
Zurück zum Zitat Mas-Colell A, Whinston MD, Green J: Microeconomic Theory. 1995, Oxford, Oxford University Press Mas-Colell A, Whinston MD, Green J: Microeconomic Theory. 1995, Oxford, Oxford University Press
25.
Zurück zum Zitat Dong H, Kouyate B, Cairns J, Mugisha F, Sauerborn R: Willingness-to-pay for community-based insurance in Burkina Faso. Health Econ. 2003, 12: 849-862. 10.1002/hec.771.PubMedCrossRef Dong H, Kouyate B, Cairns J, Mugisha F, Sauerborn R: Willingness-to-pay for community-based insurance in Burkina Faso. Health Econ. 2003, 12: 849-862. 10.1002/hec.771.PubMedCrossRef
26.
Zurück zum Zitat Dong H, Mugisha F, Gbangou A, Kouyate B, Sauerborn R: The feasibility of community-based insurance in Burkina Faso. Health Policy. 2004, 69: 45-53. 10.1016/j.healthpol.2003.12.001.PubMedCrossRef Dong H, Mugisha F, Gbangou A, Kouyate B, Sauerborn R: The feasibility of community-based insurance in Burkina Faso. Health Policy. 2004, 69: 45-53. 10.1016/j.healthpol.2003.12.001.PubMedCrossRef
27.
Zurück zum Zitat Dong H, Kouyate B, Cairns J, Sauerborn R: Differential willingness of household heads to pay community-based health insurance premia for themselves and other household members. Health Policy Plan. 2004, 19: 120-126. 10.1093/heapol/czh014.PubMedCrossRef Dong H, Kouyate B, Cairns J, Sauerborn R: Differential willingness of household heads to pay community-based health insurance premia for themselves and other household members. Health Policy Plan. 2004, 19: 120-126. 10.1093/heapol/czh014.PubMedCrossRef
28.
Zurück zum Zitat Dong H, Kouyate B, Snow R, Mugisha F, Sauerborn R: Gender’s effect on willingness-to-pay for community-based insurance in Burkina Faso. Health Policy. 2003, 64: 153-162. 10.1016/S0168-8510(02)00144-6.PubMedCrossRef Dong H, Kouyate B, Snow R, Mugisha F, Sauerborn R: Gender’s effect on willingness-to-pay for community-based insurance in Burkina Faso. Health Policy. 2003, 64: 153-162. 10.1016/S0168-8510(02)00144-6.PubMedCrossRef
29.
Zurück zum Zitat Binam J, Onana Y, Nkelzok V: Community prepayment of health care and estimation of the willingness to pay in Cameroon: evidence of rural households in the Centre region. 2004, Yaounde, Institute of Agricultural Research for Development Binam J, Onana Y, Nkelzok V: Community prepayment of health care and estimation of the willingness to pay in Cameroon: evidence of rural households in the Centre region. 2004, Yaounde, Institute of Agricultural Research for Development
30.
Zurück zum Zitat Binam J, Nkama A, Nkenda R: Estimating the willingness to pay for community health prepayment schemes in rural area: a case study of the use of contingent valuation surveys in centre Cameroon. 2004, Yaounde, Institute of Agricultural Research for Development Binam J, Nkama A, Nkenda R: Estimating the willingness to pay for community health prepayment schemes in rural area: a case study of the use of contingent valuation surveys in centre Cameroon. 2004, Yaounde, Institute of Agricultural Research for Development
31.
Zurück zum Zitat Mathiyazhagan K: Willingness to pay for rural health insurance through community participation in India. International J Health Plann Manage. 1998, 13: 47-67. 10.1002/(SICI)1099-1751(199801/03)13:1<47::AID-HPM495>3.0.CO;2-I.CrossRef Mathiyazhagan K: Willingness to pay for rural health insurance through community participation in India. International J Health Plann Manage. 1998, 13: 47-67. 10.1002/(SICI)1099-1751(199801/03)13:1<47::AID-HPM495>3.0.CO;2-I.CrossRef
32.
Zurück zum Zitat Asgary A, Willis K, Taghvaei AA, Rafeian M: Estimating rural households' willingness to pay for health insurance. Eur J of Health Econ. 2004, 5: 209-215. 10.1007/s10198-004-0233-6.CrossRef Asgary A, Willis K, Taghvaei AA, Rafeian M: Estimating rural households' willingness to pay for health insurance. Eur J of Health Econ. 2004, 5: 209-215. 10.1007/s10198-004-0233-6.CrossRef
33.
Zurück zum Zitat Ataguba J, Ichoku EH, Fonta W, Okpanachi A, Okon U: An estimation of the willingness to pay for community healthcare risk-sharing prepayment scheme and the medical poverty trap: evidence from rural Nigeria. 5th Poverty and Economic Policy (PEP) Research Network General Meeting. 2006, Addis Ababa, Ethiopia Ataguba J, Ichoku EH, Fonta W, Okpanachi A, Okon U: An estimation of the willingness to pay for community healthcare risk-sharing prepayment scheme and the medical poverty trap: evidence from rural Nigeria. 5th Poverty and Economic Policy (PEP) Research Network General Meeting. 2006, Addis Ababa, Ethiopia
34.
Zurück zum Zitat Asenso-Oykere W, Osei-Akoto I, Anum A, Appiah E: Willingness to pay for health in a developing economy. A pilot study of the informal sector of Ghana using contingent valuation. Health Policy. 1997, 42: 223-237. 10.1016/S0168-8510(97)00069-9.CrossRef Asenso-Oykere W, Osei-Akoto I, Anum A, Appiah E: Willingness to pay for health in a developing economy. A pilot study of the informal sector of Ghana using contingent valuation. Health Policy. 1997, 42: 223-237. 10.1016/S0168-8510(97)00069-9.CrossRef
35.
Zurück zum Zitat Ying XH, Hu TW, Ren J, Chen W, Xu K, Huang JH: Demand for private health insurance in Chinese urban areas. Health Econ. 2007 Ying XH, Hu TW, Ren J, Chen W, Xu K, Huang JH: Demand for private health insurance in Chinese urban areas. Health Econ. 2007
36.
Zurück zum Zitat Chen X: China's city hierarchy, urban policy and spatial development in the 1980s. Urban Stud. 1991, 28: 341-367. 10.1080/00420989120080391.CrossRef Chen X: China's city hierarchy, urban policy and spatial development in the 1980s. Urban Stud. 1991, 28: 341-367. 10.1080/00420989120080391.CrossRef
37.
Zurück zum Zitat Ministry of Health Centre for Health Statistics and Information: Report on the results of the 2004 National Health Services Survey. 2004, Beijing, Ministry of Health Ministry of Health Centre for Health Statistics and Information: Report on the results of the 2004 National Health Services Survey. 2004, Beijing, Ministry of Health
38.
Zurück zum Zitat Ryan M, Scott DA, Reeves C, Bate A, van Teijlingen ER, Russell EM, Napper M, Robb CM: Eliciting public preferences for healthcare: a systematic review of techniques. Health Technol Assess. 2001, 5: 1-186.PubMedCrossRef Ryan M, Scott DA, Reeves C, Bate A, van Teijlingen ER, Russell EM, Napper M, Robb CM: Eliciting public preferences for healthcare: a systematic review of techniques. Health Technol Assess. 2001, 5: 1-186.PubMedCrossRef
39.
Zurück zum Zitat Mitchell R, Carson R: Using surveys to value public goods: the contingent valuation method. 1993, Washington, DC, Resources for the Future Mitchell R, Carson R: Using surveys to value public goods: the contingent valuation method. 1993, Washington, DC, Resources for the Future
40.
Zurück zum Zitat Klose T: The contingent valuation method in health care. Health Policy. 1999, 47: 97-123. 10.1016/S0168-8510(99)00010-X.PubMedCrossRef Klose T: The contingent valuation method in health care. Health Policy. 1999, 47: 97-123. 10.1016/S0168-8510(99)00010-X.PubMedCrossRef
41.
Zurück zum Zitat Ryan M, Scott D, Donaldson C: Valuing health care using willingness to pay: a comparison of the payment card and dichotomous choice methods. J Health Econ. 2004, 23: 237-258. 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2003.09.003.PubMedCrossRef Ryan M, Scott D, Donaldson C: Valuing health care using willingness to pay: a comparison of the payment card and dichotomous choice methods. J Health Econ. 2004, 23: 237-258. 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2003.09.003.PubMedCrossRef
42.
Zurück zum Zitat Russell S, Fox-Rushby, Arhin D: Willingness and ability to pay for health care: a selection of methods and issues. Health Policy Plan. 1995, 10: 94-101. 10.1093/heapol/10.1.94.PubMedCrossRef Russell S, Fox-Rushby, Arhin D: Willingness and ability to pay for health care: a selection of methods and issues. Health Policy Plan. 1995, 10: 94-101. 10.1093/heapol/10.1.94.PubMedCrossRef
43.
Zurück zum Zitat Hanley N, Ryan M, Wright R: Estimating the monetary value of health care: lessons from environmental economics. Health Econ. 2003, 12: 3-16. 10.1002/hec.763.PubMedCrossRef Hanley N, Ryan M, Wright R: Estimating the monetary value of health care: lessons from environmental economics. Health Econ. 2003, 12: 3-16. 10.1002/hec.763.PubMedCrossRef
44.
Zurück zum Zitat Wuhan Yearbook Society: Wuhan yearbook. 1998, Wuhan, Publishing Department of the Wuhan Geographic Annals Collection Committee Wuhan Yearbook Society: Wuhan yearbook. 1998, Wuhan, Publishing Department of the Wuhan Geographic Annals Collection Committee
45.
Zurück zum Zitat Hussmanns R: Developments in the design and implementation of informal sector and similar surveys – a review of national practices and experiences. 1998, Geneva, International Labour Office Hussmanns R: Developments in the design and implementation of informal sector and similar surveys – a review of national practices and experiences. 1998, Geneva, International Labour Office
46.
Zurück zum Zitat Lohr S: Sampling: design and analysis. 1999, Pacific Grove, Duxbury Press Lohr S: Sampling: design and analysis. 1999, Pacific Grove, Duxbury Press
47.
Zurück zum Zitat Holt DH: Discussion of the paper by Verma, V., C. Scott and C. O'Muircheartaigh: sample designs and sampling errors for the World Fertility Survey. J R Stat Soc [Ser A]. 1980, 143: 468-514. Holt DH: Discussion of the paper by Verma, V., C. Scott and C. O'Muircheartaigh: sample designs and sampling errors for the World Fertility Survey. J R Stat Soc [Ser A]. 1980, 143: 468-514.
48.
Zurück zum Zitat Hubei Province Provincial Government: Announcement of the People's Provincial Government about the publication and distribution of the "universal plan for a basic health insurance system for employees and workers in cities and townships in Hubei Province". 1999, Wuhan Hubei Province Provincial Government: Announcement of the People's Provincial Government about the publication and distribution of the "universal plan for a basic health insurance system for employees and workers in cities and townships in Hubei Province". 1999, Wuhan
49.
Zurück zum Zitat Ministry of Labour and Social Security, Ministry of Health, National Administrative Office for Health and Pharmaceuticals: Provisory management methods of the fixed health care organisation of the urban basic health insurance for employees and workers. Chinese Journal of Health Care Quality Management. 1999, 3: 111-112. Ministry of Labour and Social Security, Ministry of Health, National Administrative Office for Health and Pharmaceuticals: Provisory management methods of the fixed health care organisation of the urban basic health insurance for employees and workers. Chinese Journal of Health Care Quality Management. 1999, 3: 111-112.
50.
Zurück zum Zitat Labour Office of Yichang City: Collection of materials concerning the basic health insurance system for enterprise workers and employees in Yichang City. 1998, Yichang Labour Office of Yichang City: Collection of materials concerning the basic health insurance system for enterprise workers and employees in Yichang City. 1998, Yichang
51.
Zurück zum Zitat Yip W, Hsiao WC: Medical savings accounts: lessons from China. Health Aff (Millwood). 1997, 16: 244-251. 10.1377/hlthaff.16.6.244.CrossRef Yip W, Hsiao WC: Medical savings accounts: lessons from China. Health Aff (Millwood). 1997, 16: 244-251. 10.1377/hlthaff.16.6.244.CrossRef
52.
Zurück zum Zitat Whynes DK, Frew EJ, Wolstenholme JL: Willingness-to-pay and demand curves: a comparison of results obtained using different elicitation formats. Int J Health Care Finance Econ. 2005, 5: 369-386. 10.1007/s10754-005-4014-2.PubMedCrossRef Whynes DK, Frew EJ, Wolstenholme JL: Willingness-to-pay and demand curves: a comparison of results obtained using different elicitation formats. Int J Health Care Finance Econ. 2005, 5: 369-386. 10.1007/s10754-005-4014-2.PubMedCrossRef
53.
Zurück zum Zitat Tang J: Report on poverty and anti-poverty in urban China. 2003, Beijing, Huaxia Publishing House Tang J: Report on poverty and anti-poverty in urban China. 2003, Beijing, Huaxia Publishing House
54.
Zurück zum Zitat Fankhauser S, Tol R, Pearce DW: The aggregation of climate change damages: a welfare theoretic approach. Environ Resour Econ. 1997, 10: 249-266. 10.1023/A:1026420425961.CrossRef Fankhauser S, Tol R, Pearce DW: The aggregation of climate change damages: a welfare theoretic approach. Environ Resour Econ. 1997, 10: 249-266. 10.1023/A:1026420425961.CrossRef
55.
Zurück zum Zitat Kula E: Social welfare weights in investment appraisal: the case of India. J Reg Anal Pol. 2002, 32: 99-114. Kula E: Social welfare weights in investment appraisal: the case of India. J Reg Anal Pol. 2002, 32: 99-114.
56.
Zurück zum Zitat Squire L, Van der Tak HG: Economic analysis of projects. 1975, Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University Press Squire L, Van der Tak HG: Economic analysis of projects. 1975, Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University Press
57.
Zurück zum Zitat Kula E: Estimation of a social rate of interest for India. J Agr Econ. 2004, 55: 91-99.CrossRef Kula E: Estimation of a social rate of interest for India. J Agr Econ. 2004, 55: 91-99.CrossRef
58.
Zurück zum Zitat Evans D: The elasticity of marginal utility of consumption: estimates for 20 OECD countries. Fisc Stud. 2005, 26: 197-224. 10.1111/j.1475-5890.2005.00010.x.CrossRef Evans D: The elasticity of marginal utility of consumption: estimates for 20 OECD countries. Fisc Stud. 2005, 26: 197-224. 10.1111/j.1475-5890.2005.00010.x.CrossRef
59.
Zurück zum Zitat Evans D, Sezer H: Social discount rate for six major countries. App Econ Lett. 2004, 11: 557-560. 10.1080/135048504200028007.CrossRef Evans D, Sezer H: Social discount rate for six major countries. App Econ Lett. 2004, 11: 557-560. 10.1080/135048504200028007.CrossRef
60.
Zurück zum Zitat Blue EN, Tweeten C: The estimation of marginal utility of income for application to agricultural policy analysis. Agr Econ. 1997, 16: 155-169. 10.1016/S0169-5150(96)01207-8.CrossRef Blue EN, Tweeten C: The estimation of marginal utility of income for application to agricultural policy analysis. Agr Econ. 1997, 16: 155-169. 10.1016/S0169-5150(96)01207-8.CrossRef
61.
Zurück zum Zitat Kaplow L: Concavity of utility, concavity of welfare, and redistribution of income. John M Olin Center for Law, Economics, and Business Discussion Paper 437. 2003, Cambridge, MA, Harvard Law School Kaplow L: Concavity of utility, concavity of welfare, and redistribution of income. John M Olin Center for Law, Economics, and Business Discussion Paper 437. 2003, Cambridge, MA, Harvard Law School
62.
Zurück zum Zitat Stewart MB: On least squares estimation when the dependent variable is grouped. Rev Econ Stud. 1983, 50: 737-753. 10.2307/2297773.CrossRef Stewart MB: On least squares estimation when the dependent variable is grouped. Rev Econ Stud. 1983, 50: 737-753. 10.2307/2297773.CrossRef
63.
Zurück zum Zitat Donaldson C, Jones AM, Mapp T, Olson JA: Limited dependent variables in willingness to pay studies: applications in health care. Appl Econ. 1998, 30: 667-677. 10.1080/000368498325651.CrossRef Donaldson C, Jones AM, Mapp T, Olson JA: Limited dependent variables in willingness to pay studies: applications in health care. Appl Econ. 1998, 30: 667-677. 10.1080/000368498325651.CrossRef
64.
Zurück zum Zitat Arin T, Kramer RA: Divers’ willingness to pay to visit marine sanctuaries: an exploratory study. Ocean Coast Manage. 2002, 45: 171-183. 10.1016/S0964-5691(02)00049-2.CrossRef Arin T, Kramer RA: Divers’ willingness to pay to visit marine sanctuaries: an exploratory study. Ocean Coast Manage. 2002, 45: 171-183. 10.1016/S0964-5691(02)00049-2.CrossRef
65.
Zurück zum Zitat Xu Z, Cheng G, Zhang Z, Su Z, Loomis J: Applying contingent valuation in China to measure the economic value of restoring ecosystem services in Ejina region. Ecol Econ. 2003, 44: 345-358. 10.1016/S0921-8009(02)00280-X.CrossRef Xu Z, Cheng G, Zhang Z, Su Z, Loomis J: Applying contingent valuation in China to measure the economic value of restoring ecosystem services in Ejina region. Ecol Econ. 2003, 44: 345-358. 10.1016/S0921-8009(02)00280-X.CrossRef
66.
Zurück zum Zitat Froot KA: Consistent covariance matrix estimation with cross-sectional dependence and heteroskedasticity in financial data. J Financ Quant Anal. 1989, 24: 333-355. 10.2307/2330815.CrossRef Froot KA: Consistent covariance matrix estimation with cross-sectional dependence and heteroskedasticity in financial data. J Financ Quant Anal. 1989, 24: 333-355. 10.2307/2330815.CrossRef
67.
Zurück zum Zitat Rösner HJ: China's health insurance system in transformation: preliminary assessment, and policy suggestions. International Social Security Review. 2004, 57: 65-90. 10.1111/j.1468-246X.2004.00195.x.CrossRef Rösner HJ: China's health insurance system in transformation: preliminary assessment, and policy suggestions. International Social Security Review. 2004, 57: 65-90. 10.1111/j.1468-246X.2004.00195.x.CrossRef
68.
Zurück zum Zitat Integrated Market Information (IMI): IMI yearbook of consumer behaviours and life patterns. 2001, Beijing, Beijing Broadcasting Institute Press Integrated Market Information (IMI): IMI yearbook of consumer behaviours and life patterns. 2001, Beijing, Beijing Broadcasting Institute Press
69.
Zurück zum Zitat McKelvey R, Zavoina W: A statistical model for the analysis of ordinal level dependent variables. J Math Sociol. 1975, 4: 103-120.CrossRef McKelvey R, Zavoina W: A statistical model for the analysis of ordinal level dependent variables. J Math Sociol. 1975, 4: 103-120.CrossRef
70.
Zurück zum Zitat Smith R, Abel Olsen J, Harris A: A review of methodological issues in the conduct of willingness-to-pay studies in health care: issues in the analysis and interpretation of WTP data. Centre for Health Program Evaluation Working Paper 86. 1999, West Heidelberg, Monash University Smith R, Abel Olsen J, Harris A: A review of methodological issues in the conduct of willingness-to-pay studies in health care: issues in the analysis and interpretation of WTP data. Centre for Health Program Evaluation Working Paper 86. 1999, West Heidelberg, Monash University
71.
Zurück zum Zitat National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA), Arrow K, Solow R, Portney P, Leamer E, Radner R, Schuman H: Report of the NOAA panel of contingent valuation. Federal Register. 1993, 58: 4601-4614. National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA), Arrow K, Solow R, Portney P, Leamer E, Radner R, Schuman H: Report of the NOAA panel of contingent valuation. Federal Register. 1993, 58: 4601-4614.
72.
Zurück zum Zitat Johannesson M: Theory and methods of economic evaluation of health care. 1996, Dordrecht, The Netherlands, Kluwer Academic PublishersCrossRef Johannesson M: Theory and methods of economic evaluation of health care. 1996, Dordrecht, The Netherlands, Kluwer Academic PublishersCrossRef
73.
Zurück zum Zitat Zhan S, Wang L, Yin A, Blas E: Revenue-driven in TB control – three cases in China. Int J Health Plann Manage. 2004, 19 Suppl 1: S63-78. 10.1002/hpm.778.PubMedCrossRef Zhan S, Wang L, Yin A, Blas E: Revenue-driven in TB control – three cases in China. Int J Health Plann Manage. 2004, 19 Suppl 1: S63-78. 10.1002/hpm.778.PubMedCrossRef
74.
Zurück zum Zitat Meng Q, Sun Q, Hearst N: Hospital charge exemptions for the poor in Shandong, China. Health Policy Plan. 2002, 17 Suppl: 56-63. 10.1093/heapol/17.suppl_1.56.PubMedCrossRef Meng Q, Sun Q, Hearst N: Hospital charge exemptions for the poor in Shandong, China. Health Policy Plan. 2002, 17 Suppl: 56-63. 10.1093/heapol/17.suppl_1.56.PubMedCrossRef
75.
Zurück zum Zitat Dong W: Can health care financing policy be emulated? The Singaporean medical savings accounts model and its Shanghai replica. J Public Health (Oxf). 2006, 28: 209-214. 10.1093/pubmed/fdl023.CrossRef Dong W: Can health care financing policy be emulated? The Singaporean medical savings accounts model and its Shanghai replica. J Public Health (Oxf). 2006, 28: 209-214. 10.1093/pubmed/fdl023.CrossRef
76.
Zurück zum Zitat Wu M, Xin Y, Wang H, Yu W: Private and public cross-subsidization: financing Beijing's health-insurance reform. Health Policy. 2005, 72: 41-52. 10.1016/j.healthpol.2004.06.007.PubMedCrossRef Wu M, Xin Y, Wang H, Yu W: Private and public cross-subsidization: financing Beijing's health-insurance reform. Health Policy. 2005, 72: 41-52. 10.1016/j.healthpol.2004.06.007.PubMedCrossRef
78.
Zurück zum Zitat Guan Z: Economic transition and health insurance system reform in urban China. 2003, Beijing, National Institute for Social Insurance Guan Z: Economic transition and health insurance system reform in urban China. 2003, Beijing, National Institute for Social Insurance
80.
Zurück zum Zitat City Government of Wuhan: Wuhan City regulation about basic health insurance for urban informal sector workers. 2004, Wuhan City Government of Wuhan: Wuhan City regulation about basic health insurance for urban informal sector workers. 2004, Wuhan
81.
Zurück zum Zitat Dong W: Healthcare-financing reforms in transitional society: a Shanghai experience. J Health Popul Nutr. 2003, 21: 223-234.PubMed Dong W: Healthcare-financing reforms in transitional society: a Shanghai experience. J Health Popul Nutr. 2003, 21: 223-234.PubMed
82.
Zurück zum Zitat Xiang B: Migration and health in China: problems, obstacles and solutions. Asia Metacentre Research Paper Series 17. 2003, Singapore, Asian Metacentre for Population and Sustainable Development Analysis Xiang B: Migration and health in China: problems, obstacles and solutions. Asia Metacentre Research Paper Series 17. 2003, Singapore, Asian Metacentre for Population and Sustainable Development Analysis
84.
Zurück zum Zitat Monheit AC: Persistence in health expenditures in the short run: prevalence and consequences. Med Care. 2003, 41: III53-III64.PubMedCrossRef Monheit AC: Persistence in health expenditures in the short run: prevalence and consequences. Med Care. 2003, 41: III53-III64.PubMedCrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Willingness to pay for social health insurance among informal sector workers in Wuhan, China: a contingent valuation study
verfasst von
Till Bärnighausen
Yuanli Liu
Xinping Zhang
Rainer Sauerborn
Publikationsdatum
01.12.2007
Verlag
BioMed Central
Erschienen in
BMC Health Services Research / Ausgabe 1/2007
Elektronische ISSN: 1472-6963
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1186/1472-6963-7-114

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2007

BMC Health Services Research 1/2007 Zur Ausgabe